The consumerist masses show little interest towards the true use-value of a given commodity, the intrinsic utility of it; but rather, give more heed to the items that are convincingly engineered to appear as appealing but are, nonetheless, devoid of satisfaction. People think they are doing one thing – purchasing a satisfying item – when in fact they are doing the complete opposite – setting themselves up for the consumer trap: the re-emergence of desire. On the surface, it is a self-liberating process; but deeper down, where it matters, it is a subtle act of subjugation to capitalist ideals
Before I
proceed it is important to contemplate what exactly individualism is. Obviously
it has something to do with the individual, acting autonomously in pursuit of
their own personalised goals; in fact, that is pretty much all there is to it. Under
individualism the individual is assigned a status of superiority, of
integrality (Fischer, 2008) . Its opposite, collectivism (the
promotion of group coherence and action), is demoted to inferiority, which
serves as an explanatory reason as to why individualism is cynical of, even
hostile towards, the government. It comes back to Adam Smith’s invisible hand,
of how a society controlled purely by the volitions of individuals will
maximise societal well-being (Lehrer, 2001) . Individualised as a society, politics
is radically changed, moving in the direction of anti-institutionalism. Coincidental
with these shifts towards individualism and consumerism is yet another, this
time from materialism to postmaterialism (don’t worry these will be explained).
In days gone by the sociological doctrine of materialism was deemed most
appropriate for society, emphasising a high rate of economic growth and order
in society. With these objectives in mind the government played an integral
role in societal proceedings. Today, however, these materialist values have
been left in antiquity, outmoded and inappropriate. Instead a more
individualised set of beliefs have come to the fore, under the umbrella term of
postmodernism. With this change the values of ‘self-expression, quality of
life, freedom of speech, and self-determination’ have risen to preeminence (Halman, 1996) . The dual forces of
individualism and postmaterialism idolise individuality and self-expression,
both of which can be altered through the medium of consumerism. Putting more
emphasis on the individual works in the favour of consumerism, a process that
is premised on the image of oneself, and how to better this image. If we flip
the scenario upside-down, to one where collectivism and communitarianism predominate,
an emphasis is placed on group-based activities; it would disrupt the business happy
relations of today, as people will think of others rather than themselves, and
will not feel reify their consumerist urges. When commentators refer to
individualism as the “a basic right to individual autonomy. It means not having
anyone tell us what to do, not having to listen if they do, not having to
conform. It means having the capacity to make our own decisions, rather than
simply living up to the expectations of community or fulfilling obligations to someone
else” (Wuthnow, 1991) (p.12). From this perspective the
perception of government dramatically changes from a caring overseer to a nosey
repulsive oppressor – the implications of which will be discussed later. Individualism
is not one unchangeable singular belief, indeed, it has various varieties. To
digress slightly from the topic in discussion – consumerism – one such variant
is utilitarian individualism. It assigns ultimate importance to personal
interest, personal responsibility, accomplishment, and material success. Which
means, by extension, a desensitisation towards other people’s woes, a sort of
Darwinistic outlook on life – the attitude of “those with very little are
usually deserving of their poverty” being characteristic of this belief. A
society of self-interested utility-maximising individuals is one in which
welfare programs are viewed as condoning indolence and idleness. People therefore hold no
reservations about retrenching government payouts, as in their eyes the
recipient is undeserving and parasitic. So for those wondering why there is a
distinct lack of action against austerity, there is part of the reason.
Individualism
fits in nicely with consumerism in particular and capitalism more generally.
One of the traits of individualistic folk is their preoccupation with how they
compare against others; relative, not absolute, improvements take priority.
They look at one another – their fellowman – as something to better, a
symbolisation of competition. As a lifeform, competition is and always has been
a necessary and inevitable characteristic of all conscious beings, ever since
the dinosaurs graced the planet. Dominance was asserted through instinctive and
often deadly violence. Today, in a world so utterly different, competition
still ensues, but is battled through the avenue of materialistic possessions, of
one’s superficial appearance – a slight difference, then. An individualistic
society is one in which collectivism and communitarianism are lost; people,
rather than cooperative and helping, are competitive and selfish. Stratified in
our de facto social standings, each with a differing degree of materialistic
conspicuity, we bequeath to the next generation, to our posterity, the values
of narcissism. Stepping outside of this conformist way of thinking, and
interacting with somebody of a different social standing is ab absurdo. In this sense, consumerism
acts as a consolidative mechanism of a primitive class system, as it allows
the rich to symbolise their wealth through the clothes they wear and the cars
they drive. Consumers aim for self-gratification and self-worth through the
medium of materialism, but only end up, counterproductively, inducing
self-estranged tendencies – am I truly satisfied, is the question that bedevils
the consumer’s mind. When I think about
the current political, economic, and social climates – conservatism,
neoliberalism, and postmaterialism - there is a clear relationship between all
three ideologies and the widespread practice of fiscal cutbacks and austerity.
On the one hand, government debt has been metamorphosed into some unbearable
liability, that needs serving urgently, at all costs. Selling off publicly
owned utilities is now on the discussion board. The revenue can then be used to
tackle some of the government debt, as the proponents of privatisation smugly state.
Everything is being turned over to the theology of profit, and it only weakens
the citizen’s ability to escape the almost-claustrophobic confines of
capitalism. Only a small minority are actively mobilising and standing against
these large transfers of wealth; for the remaining majority, on the other hand,
austerity and privatisation are seen in a more contrived light, making them
indifferent towards this marginalisation of the government. There are two main
problems inherent in the process of consumerism. On the one hand it is
responsible for socialising whole populations into insatiable consumers, to the
detriment of the environment principally, but also (paradoxically) to the
participatory individual per se. (Paradoxically because they are forever
unfulfilled, as consumerism self-perpetuates itself. It also destroys social
cohesion and places the self above others). Then, on the other hand, it
encourages an unconscionable misallocation of resources, away from genuine
needs to frivolous and inessential ones. This climate of repugnance
towards the government makes itself apparent in the stance taken by consumers when income
taxation is in discussion. Following an announcement for heightened tax rates,
there will be an uproar of hostility emanating from the followers of
consumerism. On the contrary, people have been spoon-fed the belief that
reduced tax rates – from the richest to the poorest – will allow for more
consumption-derived pleasure (Wolff, 2006) .
The irony in all this, of course, is that the animosity towards the government,
and the demand for lower tax rates, will affect the populace adversely in the
form of lower government spending and vitiated amenities. There is nothing
democratic about consumerism; only those with the requisite wherewithal can
realise and indulge in the practice. There is a parasitic, self-reinforcing
relationship between this fixation of consumption and free-market ideology.
Those who subscribe to the former may not necessarily subscribe to the latter;
the chances are though, is that, in fact, they do. The opposite of free-market
ideology – governmentalism – has connotations with more extractive tax-rates,
and thus, by implication, a coercive appropriation of one’s purchasing power (Schneiderman, 1998) . Their ability to
consume, in turn, is eroded away, which creates a justification – in the eyes
of the devout consumer – for minimal government interventionism. Notwithstanding
the obvious benefits of redistributive-purposed taxation – to help the less
fortunate – the dual forces of consumerism and individualism have reduced
empathy and sympathy to atrophy.
Through
the unremitting bombardment of advertising and marketing, the human mind,
out of sheer capitulation to informational overload, inculcates the values of
consumerism. To become a bona fide consumer one has to inculcate a fixation
with their bodily appearance; how one looks is the sine qua non of consumerism. This
self-consciousness of one’s appearance can be changed (or ostensibly improved)
through consumptive behaviour, through the purchase of yet more ultimately
needless commodities (Bauman Z. , 1983) . It is a temporary palliative, a brief
but quickly extinguished moment of satisfaction, which turns into longing and
unhappiness. In a world where commodified items control the actions and
behaviourisms of whole populations, the marginalised non-commodified avenues to
contentedness – socially cohesive practices, which emphasis communality and
interaction – are ignored and sidelined (Bauer et al., 2012) . That consumerism is painted in such
beautiful(ly idealistic) colours, people do not feel overly concerned with
being exploited to the extent that they are. It is a necessary and tolerable
unpleasantry to acquire their wage to partake in “the paradise of shopping” (Ivanova, 2011) . People do not view
commodities as the product of labour, but as mere commodities; they overlook
the exertion that was instrumental in their creation, dehumanising these
objects of any prior human contribution. It comes back to what, in Marxist
terms, is known as commodity fetishism. Self-expression, a consciously creative
notion, has been misappropriated by consumerism and turned into something that
is manifested in what one wears. It is inevitably exclusionary, and those
without the purchasing power (or increasingly who have reached their upper
credit limit) are alienated from this consumption-driven spectacle. This idea
can be encapsulated into the saying: “I am = what I have and what I consume” (Fromm, 1976) (p.36). Producers,
with their impressive array of marketing mechanism, manipulate people into
purchasing goods, commodities, of no intrinsic value. Indeed this change marks
a transition away from the subjectification to objectification of the consumer;
from individuals being subjects within the consumerist process, to constitutive
cogs, mere objects. Producers have hijacked positive abstractions –
"success," "sophistication," "hipness,"
"independence," etc., - into concrete realisations through the medium
of consumption (Morris, 2001) . The representative values of
commodities are now ordered in terms of subjective significance, with extrinsic
values subordinating intrinsic ones. It comes back to what French sociologist,
Jean Baudrillard, described as the “political economy of the sign”, a society wherein the connotative values of a good has primacy over its actual use value.
As consumers, we would choose a “trendy, fashionable pair of trainers”, over
another pair of superior durability, comfortability, and affordability.
Consumerism is construed as a readily available avenue to the valorisation of
individualised identity. Because consumption is underpinned by this
over-obsessive fascination with sign values – of what something symbolises - the
chances of reappropriation are slim. Consumerism, like most important practices,
has its very own culture and ideology – “a coherent set of practices, attitudes
and values, based on advertising and the mass media but permeating the whole
social structure, that encourages ever expanding consumption of consumer goods”
(p.260). It was Italian Marxist Antonio Gramsci who famously formulated the notion of
cultural hegemony, an instance in which the general populace assimilates the
ruling party’s culture. On this qualification, therefore, consumerism can be seen
as exhibiting hegemonic status. It is akin to a Ponzi scheme, a perpetual and
hopeful game of creating new goods or services before the prior ones stultify.
To put
a Marxist label on consumerism, and particularly its idiosyncratic
culture-ideology, it would constitute a chunk of the superstructure (which is
then constituted by a whole multitude of interactions, encouraging individuals,
sometimes unwittingly, sometimes consciously, into the realm of consumerist
“paradise”). The process has also caught
the attention of the Frankfurt School, with famous critical theorist,
Herbert Marcuse, formulating the dichotomy of “true” or “false” needs, to
distinguish between what is necessary, and what is merely desirable but
inessential. From the above, it should hopefully be clear that the needs which
consumerism depends on, which perpetuate its continuance, are the false ones.
That the commodification of anything that is plausibly commodifiable is so
successful, is because it brings about an extraneous and extrinsic
satisfaction; it does not address intrinsic yearning, the wants that are of
significance. To reiterate: consumerism is merely palliative, a soothing yet
insufficient device to satisfy subproblems, the ones attached to the source of
the discontentment. The fact consumerism is premised on the constant and
unending consumption of materialistic items, may (though unlikely) be the cause
of its undoing. Workers so fed-up with their ounce of purchasing power will
demand, more and more ferociously, greater and greater wages, in the end
creating the fermenting conditions for a working class revolt. And this isn’t
just exaggerated scaremongering. This very situation – a proletarian revolution
– was documented, in waves, during the year of 1989 across Eastern Europe (Bauman Z. , 1992) (p.170).
Psychology
and consumerism pretty much go hand in hand. How the brain functions is
important for the success and sustainment of consumerism. When our ‘biological
needs’ are satisfied (to steal a phrase from Maslow’s hierarchy of needs), new
desires are created, which are increasingly orientated towards materialist
possessions. An iterative cycle of “dream, desire, acquisition, and
disillusionment” is spawned (Migone, 2007) , whereby consumers experience infatuation
towards a particular good, only for unfulfillment to kick-in after purchase. In
a society where the individual is most important, there is a need to openly
exhibit one’s status. That there just happens to be an ideological force as
consumerism which fits the criterion for this exhibition of individualism is
suspiciously coincidental. Advertising is no longer restricted to aesthetics, but has moved into the psychological realm; it prizes itself in its ability to entrap the sensory neurons in the brain, those little receptors which light up ecstatically if prompted by something visually and psychologically appealing. In other words, advertising depends on the manipulation, both consciously and subliminally, of emotions (Cahill, 2001) . The misery of others has been overexposed to such an extent that people are now desensitised to these systemic problems (a worrisome thought in itself). We don’t find homelessness emotive anymore, but new avant-garde fads; this, increasingly, is the only time emotion emerges to the fore. Emotionless as a population, the term post-emotionalism has been coined, to describe a society in which emotion is only evoked by artificial, not natural, stimuli; where “synthetic, quasi-emotions become the basis for widespread manipulation by self, others, and the culture industry as a whole” (p.14) (Mestrovic, 1997) . Marketing specialists understand the basics of how the human brain functions, and more importantly what triggers its stimulation. It is these triggers that are being activated by marketing ploys in order to compel an impulsive purchase (Behr, 2010) . Hunger being one example of these triggers, a fact that has not gone unnoticed by food producers. To artificially stimulate the viewer’s brain, into an impromptu desire for food – their actual hunger notwithstanding – promotions now use subliminal messages to instigate this reaction. As a process, consumerism is funny for the fact
that it turns out-of-reach luxuries, one day, into necessitates, the next
(Gummer and Goldsmith 2007: 41). Instrumental to this necessitation is the clever
but manipulative psychologically-driven marketing techniques of entities who
are responsible for the never-ending supply of consumer items – profit-hungry
corporations and their equally as profit-hungry shareholders. A Frankfurt School perspective pairs
mass culture – i.e. consumerism – with mass deception; of how consumption is
antithetical to true liberation and autonomy – the very thing it promises to
provide. Through a joint effort between advertisers and the media, this falsity
has been systematised and reinforced until an uncritical acceptance prevails.
From an early age, the collective tabula rasa of millions of children is
socialised into one in which consumerism is considered the norm, something
ordinary. To
expand on this point about advertising, there is a clear and positive
relationship between overexposure to marketing and consumerism. We have
identified consumption as a process which provides gratification, something
that allows the consumer to temporarily forget about the dissatisfaction of the
workplace. It is an effective device at diverting attention away from the
capitalist system, away from questioning its morality, its fairness, its
inclusiveness. These two environments – the consumer and working milieux –
depend on one another for their continued existence. The ease by which the
wage-provider can justify a small wage is, in part, because of consumerism. To
venture into the hedonistic paradise of consumption, the employee is willing to
accept any wage. That is one half of the duality. The other half – how working
perpetuates consumerism – relates closely to the prior point about tiny
remuneration. If the worker only has
little disposable income, the entry into the perfectionistic consumerist world
can only ever be infrequently. What I mean to say, more straight-to-the-point-ly,
is that the worker does not experience any significant diminishing marginal
returns. If everybody were filthy rich, then consumerism would quickly become
sucked of any excitement it once had, into a void of mundanity.
Conspiracy
theories are typically laughed away as not being worthy of rebuttal. But some,
indeed this one, are worth considering. Thinking about how low wages are
prolonged one begins to question why are they so depressed; the economy is
growing, so why is this not reflected in rising wages? This leads me to believe
that low wages are artificially (though subtly) preserved by those with vested
interests. What justification do I have for this claim? Nothing but simple
intuitive reasoning. As the economy acclimatised into the suffocating climate
of neoliberalism, there was a reorientation in policy: what became important
was financial services, not the traditional backbone of any economy,
manufacturing. With this growing dependence on financialisation the economy was
flooded with cheap credit, which at a time when consumption underpinned by debt
became condonable (coincidence?), encouraged people into indebtedness. Once
this choice was made, and those with a perfect credit record gave up this
pristine status for that of a debtor, people were entrapped, legally, within
the capitalist system. They have a reason to behave and be an exemplar to all
others seeking to be a emotionless citizen; debt negates the inner feelings of
dissent.
Liberty, the brother of
individualism, places a heavy emphasis on the individual, and their
self-sustaining powers. Ever since feudalism, when classical thinkers such as John
Locke and Thomas Hobbes wrote their treatises on liberalism and the invasive
state, liberty has been accorded more and more value. Of course some question
whether this liberty is indeed for everybody, or just for the wealthy; is it
one standard for all, or merely a subtle instance of double standards? It is a
point that Marx and Engels found to be true: ‘from the moment when individual
property can no longer be transformed into bourgeois property, from that
moment, you say, individuality vanishes. You must, therefore, confess that by
“individual” you mean no other person than the bourgeois’ (Marx & Friedrich, 1848). Marx was no denialist when it came to whether individuality was present in society; he accepted this fact. It was to whom, or rather to what,
this individuality was assigned that he was sceptical of. Capital, Marx
believed, was the only thing with true individuality; to capture capital (and
become a capitalist) was therefore the only possible route to individuality.
Without capital one has to offer their labour to a capitalist, thus forfeiting
individuality and autonomy. In this era, government played an important but minimalist role:
to maintain a relation were the employer can employ workers freely, and
employees can choose employment freely. There was a certain freedom in their
behaviour, workers were not coerced into a place of work. But when the choice
of employment ranged from being fully exploited to slightly less so, what this
revered freedom bought was drudgery and toil. There are means to overcome this
vulnerability, namely to unionise together and demand a higher wage. But even
unionisation was to compromise individual freedom – on the side of the
capitalist; they would no longer hold the ability to dictate and set an
appropriate price tag (in their eyes) on labour. In the times that these
debates were first sparred, and indeed also today, when liberal individualism is once again pervasive, if the government was to (mis?)appropriate the wealth of capitalists
it would be derided as an attack on one’s inalienable freedom. This was until
John S Mill postulated his views on individualism and, specifically, the
permissibility of the capitalist to accumulate and accumulate wealth. At this
juncture Mills diverged away from the (by now) conventional truisms,
highlighting the unfairness of how the capitalist contributes very little but
feels entitled to such substantial remuneration; ‘independently of any trouble
or outlay incurred by themselves. They grow richer, as it were in their sleep,
without working, risking, or economizing’ (Mill, 2004) (p.220). By merely
owning the factors of production the capitalist was able to, not out of his own
wit, intellect, or perseverance, extract
the surplus value from their overworked labour force; indeed this surplus value
came to be known as ‘unearned income’. Mills, to the disgust of fellow
liberals, was sympathetic towards the appropriation of capital from
capitalists, if it clearly derived from ‘unearned income’. The argument was
that, if the capitalist is merely profiting from their monopoly price or
because they own the factors of production, and in turn benefits from ‘unearned
income’, they are not actually qualified to accumulate this wealth (O'Flynn, 2012) . The problematic nature of individualism stems from the fact
that, when everybody thinks and acts in solely their self-interest, individual
rights and liberties are given primacy while duties and responsibilities are attenuated
and neglected (Passini, 2013) . Conflicts quickly arise between what
is optimal for the individual, on the one hand, and what is optimal for others,
on the other. All that matters is one’s individuality, and its improvement.
Opportunities may indeed present themselves, to assist others in their quest of
realising individuality, but despite the altruistic satisfaction from these
acts of benevolence, they are ignored and avoided.
Does
this theory push the bounds of realism too far, or is it reflective of reality?
While
writing this piece it did strike me, not once but on a number of occasions,
about whether the theory and critiques of consumerism are just the paranoid
ramblings of some past anti-capitalist; whose thought processes were
preprogramed to blame the capitalist system for all societal problems. Is this
self-perpetuating circle of consume, unfulfillment, on a constant repeat cycle representative
of the real world? People may not admit to behaving in this mechanistic manner,
as it will appear imperceptibly to them; this imperceptibility is after all the
beauty of modern day advertisement. That is not to deny the existence of this
circulatory cycle, just that it will be expressed in more agreeable terms, that
will go by unnoticed and not warrant a second glance. If people consciously knew
they were being patronised and tricked into purchasing items that will, at some
later point, become undesirable, then encouraging consumption in the first
place would become an impossible task. What first comes to mind are fads and
fashions. Indeed the motion by which consumption trends goes along in concert
with the latest fads and fashions would suggest this analysis to be correct. Ask
somebody do they follow these short-lived fads, and the likelihood of a yes is
much higher than when asked are they manipulated by their favourite clothing
designers. Importantly, though, they are both synonymous, and by answering yes
to second question, they are, albeit indirectly, answering yes to the first one
too.
Consumerism
and the environment together just does not work. In fact attempting to
reconcile the differences between the two is tantamount to assuaging the restiveness
of two hyperactive and obstinate children who both want the same thing; there
is no compromise. To protect the environment, consumers need to internalise the
values of sustainability and ethicality. But these conflict with what consumerism
espouses: an endless excess of consumption. In the end it comes down to one
question: as an intelligent species do we care and value for environment the most,
or that pair of trainers over there? The answer, as far as I see it, is self-evident;
but then again, in an individualised society there is a disconnection between
one’s actions and the wider implications upon the environment. That this mode
of thinking pervades the consumerist society makes this important task
particularly (though not insurmountably) difficult.
To
draw this discussion to a close it is worthwhile to touch on the effects of an
individualistic, consumerist society. Instead of valuing people for their
non-materialistic virtues – their personality, their morality, their altruism –
people regulate their human interaction in terms of what one wears, drives, or
even how one looks. And given the selectivity with where nudism is permitted,
there is no alternative to a clothes-cladded society. That people judge others
on these superficial and largely unrepresentative variables is typical of the quintessential
consumer in today’s world. Only by putting these what amount to pointless and
pretentious differences aside will a more integrative, empathetic and
sympathetic society arise. Until then, expect more narcissism, selfishness, and
general disregard for other people – including yourself (sorry!).
If you enjoyed what you've just read, could you be so kind as to press the g+1 a little further down. It means I will appear closer to the first page when somebody types, for example, a related search into Google, which given the fact I rely wholly on Facebook groups would be massively helpful for exposure. :)
Works Cited
- Bauer et al., M. A. (2012). Cuing Consumerism: Situational Materialism Undermines Personal and Social Well-Being. Psychological Science, 23(5), 517-523.
- Bauman, Z. (1983). Industrialism, Consumerism and Power. Theory, Culture & Society, 1(3), 32-43.
- Bauman, Z. (1992). Communism: A Postmortem. In Intimations of Postmodernity.
- Beabout, G. R., & Echeveria, E. J. (2002). The Culture of Consumerism: A Catholic and Personalist Critique. Journal of Markets & Morality, 5(2), 339–383.
- Behr, R. (2010). Anti-consumerism. Public Policy Research, 17(3), 123-129.
- Bocock, R. (1993). Consumption.
- Cahill, M. (2001). The Implications of Consumerism for the Transition to a Sustainable Society. Social Policy & Administration, 35(5), 627-639.
- Campbell, D. (1989). The romantic ethic and the spirit of modern consumerism.
- Fischer, C. S. (2008). Paradoxes of American Individualism. Sociological Forum, 23(2), 363-372.
- Fromm, E. (1976). To have or to be?
- Halman, L. (1996). Individualism in Individualized Society? Results from the European Value Surveys. International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 37(3), 195-214.
- Huang, J. J., Huang, M. Y., & Syu, F. K. (2010). Liberated anomie in generation next: Hyperindividualism, extreme consumerism, and social isolationism. Fooyin Journal of Health Sciences, 2(2), 41-47.
- Ivanova, M. N. (2011). Consumerism and the Crisis: Wither ‘the American Dream’? Critical Sociology, 37(3), 329-350.
- Lehrer, K. (2001). Individualism, Communitarianism and Consensus. The Journal of Ethics, 5(2), 105-120.
- Marx, K., & Friedrich, E. (1848). The Communist Manifesto.
- Mestrovic, S. (1997). Post Emotional Society.
- Migone, A. (2007). Hedonistic Consumerism: Patterns of Consumption in Contemporary Capitalism. Review of Radical Political Economics, 2, 173-200.
- Mill, J. S. (2004). Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy: Abridged.
- Morris, M. (2001). Contradictions of Post-modern Consumerism and Resistance. Studies in Political Economy, 64, 7-32.
- Mulgan, G. (1994). Connexity.
- O'Flynn, M. (2012). Capital Accumulation and the Historical Decline of Liberal Individualism. Critical Sociology, 39(4), 493-509.
- Passini, S. (2013). A binge-consuming culture: The effect of consumerism on social interactions in western societies. Culture & Psychology, 19(3), 369-390.
- Schneiderman, D. (1998). Constitutionalizing the Culture-Ideology of Consumerism. Social Legal Studies, 7(2), 213-238.
- Wolff, R. D. (2006). Ideological State Apparatuses, Consumerism, and U.S. Capitalism: Lessons for the Left. Rethinking Marxism: A Journal of Economics, Culture & Society, 17(2), 223-235.
- Wuthnow, R. (1991). Acts of compassion.
No comments:
Post a Comment