Monday 20 April 2015

Politics: why we, the electorate, need utilitarianism more than ever.

Five years have passed surreptitiously by, and the time has come around again to fake our best expressions of comprehension towards the talk of politics. There is a refreshing gust of change this time, though; we as the electorate have the power to medicate ourself once again with a repeat prescription of the same old, antiquated politics, or to be adventurous and try something entirely new; something radical. Immediately alarm bells are probably ringing in your head - and of course so they should be, it is because the word radical has been hijacked by conservatives to portend a soon-to-materialise ruinous event. It is not synonymous with historically significant events as the French Revolution, and the succeeding Reign of Terror; but ought to symbolise something that can potentially make a huge and positive difference. In this case, radical is used to signify something that is outside of the stale status quo, something at odds with what is considered – subjectively I may add  – as the conventional way of doing things. As with most decisions, there is of course some uncertainty around a radical shift, yet these choices and their potential consequences are of too much importance to merely discard due to some, small or large, possibility that it may end badly. The propaganda and falsities of the major parties are in a slow descent to being exposed for what they are, and people are beginning to wake up from their hypnotic slumbers. And yet, what we are seeing is people ignoring their convictions and choosing to espouse the very same parties that have used deceit and skullduggery to secure their vote in the past. If there ever was an almighty paradox, this is a major contender. Why would one persist in voting for a party that has condescendingly lied to them; one which has manipulated them for no other end than that of their own progression?

The rigid and age-long duopoly of the Conservatives and Labour has been placed under increasing pressure by the radical but infantile political parties of the Green Party and UKIP. Perhaps in a few years’ time, and only if their momentum is maintained or even better increased, the opportunity for the Green Party to challenge the shared hegemony will be ripe, but for the present moment, and with the looming election in mind, the party will not achieve empowerment anytime soon. Instead, yet more of the same now bilious policies will follow, with the election being a close and hotly contested toss-up between the Tories and Labour. Hotly contested is just the start of it; these two parties, though more so the Tories, are now scooping down to new levels of childish pettiness by bellowing personalised insults and defamations towards one another all in the name of their agendas. Ironically, the Green Party is doing a better job at upholding the values of etiquette and professionalism than either of the major parties. Attacking the person instead of the party’s policies is a clever tactic of diverting away from the latter, which in itself calls into question; why belittle the other parties leader if they truly believe their respective party to have the best policies?

This opportunity to step outside of mainstream politics, away from austerity, neoliberalism, and institutionalised venality, has been around for years, but it is only recently that the general populace have begun to take notice. Yet the only party offering this alternative, and I would go as far to say, refreshing doctrine, is either systematically vilified by the media, excluded outright from the media limelight, or made into laughing stock due to some exaggerated (often misquoted) statement. Gandhi was the first to recognise these desperate and spiteful tactics; he wrote: “First they ignore you, then they laugh at you, then they fight you, then you win”. If examined chronologically, there is definite resemblance to the sequential process described by Gandhi when one considers the interaction between the Green Party and the media; and I don't think this can be attributed to mere chance.

It is us, the electorate, who are affected by politics; we transfer our microscopically small share of constitutional power to the entrusting hands of politicians, who then, on our behalf, decide all aspects of government, from education to healthcare. So with that in mind, it is – and I believe this to be unchallengeable - only natural of us, the people, to expect a large degree of political virtue at best – or at the bare minimum, at least some. This notion of political virtue is important, as it helps to distinguish between a self-interested politician (or political party) and one who has the public’s interest at heart. Only with an open and explicit abnegation of self-interest for the public good is political virtue manifest.

It is in this current era of turbulence and precarity that the values of togetherness, selflessness, and thoughtfulness have been crudely replaced by individualism, narcissism, and a degenerative crisis in empathy. Unlike some countries, politics in the UK is determined through the suffrage system: for those who are legally allowed to vote, they are encouraged to pledge their support to the party whose manifesto is most closely aligned with their personal convictions and, increasingly, their financial standing. It is the individual that is the main and perhaps only consideration, not the collective. Consistency is important for all political parties; if it is compromised, and one begins to renege on old promises, voters will become disenfranchised, or worst yet pack their bags and chose a different party. For the Tories consistency is not a problem in one respect: of how they maintain their unbroken track record in implementing - what's that - yet more regressive austerity cuts, the brunt of which fall by and large on the poorest and most vulnerable in society. Neither the Tory politicians nor their superrich bankrollers are none the wiser to these consequences. Two parallel societies have sprung into existence, living in complete isolation of one another. Inhabited by the millionaires and billionaires of society, the first society enclosures themselves off from the repugnant sight of the plebeian masses; all that matters is themselves and their class; everybody else is subject to ignorance and lives in the background. They seem blissfully unaware, or perhaps even indifferent towards, the worrying trends in poverty and associated ills that their political preference brings. The second society, occupied by the common man, is one in which public services are vital, where one or two more pound above the minimum wage determines whether one can live under a roof or not.

On that note, it brings the discussion to the central point of this writing, that what is needed to remedy this sorry state of affairs is a renaissance in the interest of utilitarianism. For those to which utilitarianism is just a longer than average word without meaning, I will now provide a succinct and simple definition. As a doctrine, the idea of utilitarianism, at least in principle, is premised on the maximisation of overall social utility. To think about the present situation, one in which a small proportion of individuals have high utilities, while others, a preponderant majority have low utilities, it is clear that the principle of utilitarianism is violated. For the doctrine’s formulators, Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill, their argument would follow the logic that, to achieve a fairer and happier society, there is a need to equalise the relative utilities across all different societal classes. The analogy of a see-saw will help to visualise this effect, a utility see-saw if you will: on one end, high in the air, are the superrich, unperturbed by their fellow countryman’s poverty; then on the other end, with their feet dragging across the ground, is the remaining majority, mired by debt, eroding purchasing power, and job insecurity. The wealthy minority may be less in absolute quantity, but on account of sheer mass they win hands-down. It doesn’t have to be like this; indeed even Moses would have his work cut out facilitating a passage through the gulf between the rich and poor. People tend to forget that even humans are imperfect, and the notion of infallibility is but a fraud; not every situation can be critically analysed, and the inevitable outcome is the occasional mistake or regret. Yet people look at others with a sort of Darwinistic mindset, an unforgiving and uncompassionate way of thinking. This disconnection between one’s unfortunate socioeconomic position and others’ sympathetic reaction when faced by it has meant that people are less caring to one another.

To reverse back down this tangent to utilitarianism, we can think of one’s utility as being out of a possible score of ten. For the wealthy in society, free of the daily worries about whether the next debt interest instalment will be serviceable, or if their zero-hour contact will cover the bills this week, their utility averages between nine and ten. To move down the scale and we will pass individuals from all societal positions; for the vast majority, though - that is to say, the working class - utility can range widely from a measly four to seven, when considering averages only. Don’t take these as givens as this is supposed to be nothing more than an illustrative exercise; but I conjecture that these are accurate approximations. As the working class accounts for a significantly larger proportion of the population, the implication is that there is a worryingly large underfulifillment of utility in society. There is a necessity for the richer more fortunate members of society to recognise this underfulifillment and impute it into their political decisions; the answer they ought to consider is: what is of most importance: an extra two utility points for themselves, or an additional four or five for their poorer counterparts? The utilitarian would assert the latter, and indeed I would have to concur too – the 19th century poet, William Blake, sums this point up sombrely when he stated that “The most sublime act is to set another before you.”

Thursday 26 March 2015

I like commodities, you like commodities; everyone likes commodities! How consumerism and individualism have changed society (with some minor digressions).


Tangled in a complex web of relational connections, consumerism and Western culture come as an inextricable pair. It is not only the West either that has been infected by the ethos of consumerism, oh no, but increasingly other traditionally non-Western regions too. One could be so bold as to say consumerism has transcended into some divine weltanschauung – a universal worldview. Like the industrial revolution that came before it, consumerism, and the concomitant process of consumption, is the next pivotal historical advancement; the latest epoch. Consumerism per se teasingly offers the consumer – that is, you, myself, everyone – the opportunity of unmitigated choice. This appearance of choice is but a masquerade of superficiality; indeed, it looks like choice, but on closer inspection, it is exposed for what it is: a rigid and preconceived array of commodities which have been conjured up to exude an aura of uniqueness and individuality. Environmentalists are mortally frightened of consumerism, and for good reason. At the very heart of the process is the premise of infinite consumption: not figuratively or metaphorically speaking, but quite literally (as illogical as that may be). It doesn’t necessarily have to be about quantity either, Western societies have created the normative belief that to become a recognised and respectable citizen, one has to, out of dire necessity, own a car (Mulgan, 1994) (p.48). Car ownership holds a recognition like no other commodity. It has even been subject to prosopopoeia, a special type of personification, in which something inanimate as a car is construed as a moving manifestation of sleekness or power – purchase a car, the promotion goes, and become powerful. Those under the spell of consumerism express a burning desire to search and seek the “ultimate good”. Of course, the paradox herein, is that when this supreme item has been located, a new desire is induced, and the previous commodity loses any appeal it once had. Round and round, this cycle self-perpetuates itself, in a cyclical motion; “an apparently endless pursuit of want” (Campbell, 1989) (p. 37). Diminishing returns kick-in, and for the next transient instance of consumption, there is a need for even greater quantities to derive the same amount of satisfaction as before. This mode of living has not suddenly materialised out of nowhere, without impetus or origin. Rather, it has been encouraged through Althusserian ideological state apparatuses (ISAs) –  particularly media and education – to inculcate the seeds of consumerism into our minds and, once they germinate, our actions too. 

The consumerist masses show little interest towards the true use-value of a given commodity, the intrinsic utility of it; but rather, give more heed to the items that are convincingly engineered to appear as appealing but are, nonetheless, devoid of satisfaction. People think they are doing one thing – purchasing a satisfying item – when in fact they are doing the complete opposite – setting themselves up for the consumer trap: the re-emergence of desire. On the surface, it is a self-liberating process; but deeper down, where it matters, it is a subtle act of subjugation to capitalist ideals (Passini, 2013). We coexist in a world in which people are willing to enter indebtedness all in the name of consuming the latest fad item. The virtue of long-sightedness is of no persuasion, as people take on debt even though it means, at some eventual point, they will have to sell their labour power as repayment. Insofar as this elusive satisfaction urges people to consume, there is a growing trend of shopaholics, those individuals which consume beyond their means (into credit servitude). Instantaneous self-gratification is what matters most to the consumer, even if this means infringes on the well-being of others. We are witnessing the rise of expressive individualism. As the name suggests, this variant of individualism wishes for creativity and uniqueness of the individual, based on self-expression and hedonism. There are clear overlapping features between consumerism and expressive individualism: both are premised on the expression of individuality, indeed, they could be perceived as complementarities. By believing the individual is everything – and this is hardly a novel observation – egoism, narcissism and selfishness increase in commonality. To be astounded and surprised by this finding is to forget the central tenant of individualism: that personal freedom is more important than equality. Even more radically, some describe the deification of the individual as a form of hyperindividualism, ‘‘characterized by (a) disconnection from society, but not from the self; individuals feel free to satisfy personal needs without considering the consequences of their actions on the rest of society’’ (Huang, Huang, & Syu, 2010) (p.42). The ultimate teleological end of consumerism, like most capitalistic processes, is profit, not friendship or civic bonds. It labels consumption with more importance than interactional human experience, crowding out social activity. When one desires self-gratification it is only natural of them to exhibit a disregard for the long-term; immediacy is everything. Through the prism of hedonistic-individualism, social relations are only worthwhile for their instrumentality to a feeling of self-gratification; as soon as this is realised, however fleetingly, these relations are discarded and forgotten. It is a mode of thinking predicated upon the assumption that “buying things and pre-packaged experiences” are the means to nirvana (Bocock, 1993) (p.50). To forget about the monotony of working life, those never-ending nine till five shifts, people are cunningly lured into the consumerist way of life. It has entered and colonised the leisure sphere in part, displacing the more communal activities with an outing to the shopping centre or its Americanised counterpart, the “mall”.

Before I proceed it is important to contemplate what exactly individualism is. Obviously it has something to do with the individual, acting autonomously in pursuit of their own personalised goals; in fact, that is pretty much all there is to it. Under individualism the individual is assigned a status of superiority, of integrality (Fischer, 2008). Its opposite, collectivism (the promotion of group coherence and action), is demoted to inferiority, which serves as an explanatory reason as to why individualism is cynical of, even hostile towards, the government. It comes back to Adam Smith’s invisible hand, of how a society controlled purely by the volitions of individuals will maximise societal well-being (Lehrer, 2001). Individualised as a society, politics is radically changed, moving in the direction of anti-institutionalism. Coincidental with these shifts towards individualism and consumerism is yet another, this time from materialism to postmaterialism (don’t worry these will be explained). In days gone by the sociological doctrine of materialism was deemed most appropriate for society, emphasising a high rate of economic growth and order in society. With these objectives in mind the government played an integral role in societal proceedings. Today, however, these materialist values have been left in antiquity, outmoded and inappropriate. Instead a more individualised set of beliefs have come to the fore, under the umbrella term of postmodernism. With this change the values of ‘self-expression, quality of life, freedom of speech, and self-determination’ have risen to preeminence (Halman, 1996). The dual forces of individualism and postmaterialism idolise individuality and self-expression, both of which can be altered through the medium of consumerism. Putting more emphasis on the individual works in the favour of consumerism, a process that is premised on the image of oneself, and how to better this image. If we flip the scenario upside-down, to one where collectivism and communitarianism predominate, an emphasis is placed on group-based activities; it would disrupt the business happy relations of today, as people will think of others rather than themselves, and will not feel reify their consumerist urges. When commentators refer to individualism as the “a basic right to individual autonomy. It means not having anyone tell us what to do, not having to listen if they do, not having to conform. It means having the capacity to make our own decisions, rather than simply living up to the expectations of community or fulfilling obligations to someone else” (Wuthnow, 1991)(p.12). From this perspective the perception of government dramatically changes from a caring overseer to a nosey repulsive oppressor – the implications of which will be discussed later. Individualism is not one unchangeable singular belief, indeed, it has various varieties. To digress slightly from the topic in discussion – consumerism – one such variant is utilitarian individualism. It assigns ultimate importance to personal interest, personal responsibility, accomplishment, and material success. Which means, by extension, a desensitisation towards other people’s woes, a sort of Darwinistic outlook on life – the attitude of “those with very little are usually deserving of their poverty” being characteristic of this belief. A society of self-interested utility-maximising individuals is one in which welfare programs are viewed as condoning indolence and idleness. People therefore hold no reservations about retrenching government payouts, as in their eyes the recipient is undeserving and parasitic. So for those wondering why there is a distinct lack of action against austerity, there is part of the reason. 

Individualism fits in nicely with consumerism in particular and capitalism more generally. One of the traits of individualistic folk is their preoccupation with how they compare against others; relative, not absolute, improvements take priority. They look at one another – their fellowman – as something to better, a symbolisation of competition. As a lifeform, competition is and always has been a necessary and inevitable characteristic of all conscious beings, ever since the dinosaurs graced the planet. Dominance was asserted through instinctive and often deadly violence. Today, in a world so utterly different, competition still ensues, but is battled through the avenue of materialistic possessions, of one’s superficial appearance – a slight difference, then. An individualistic society is one in which collectivism and communitarianism are lost; people, rather than cooperative and helping, are competitive and selfish. Stratified in our de facto social standings, each with a differing degree of materialistic conspicuity, we bequeath to the next generation, to our posterity, the values of narcissism. Stepping outside of this conformist way of thinking, and interacting with somebody of a different social standing is ab absurdo. In this sense, consumerism acts as a consolidative mechanism of a primitive class system, as it allows the rich to symbolise their wealth through the clothes they wear and the cars they drive. Consumers aim for self-gratification and self-worth through the medium of materialism, but only end up, counterproductively, inducing self-estranged tendencies – am I truly satisfied, is the question that bedevils the consumer’s mind. When I think about the current political, economic, and social climates – conservatism, neoliberalism, and postmaterialism - there is a clear relationship between all three ideologies and the widespread practice of fiscal cutbacks and austerity. On the one hand, government debt has been metamorphosed into some unbearable liability, that needs serving urgently, at all costs. Selling off publicly owned utilities is now on the discussion board. The revenue can then be used to tackle some of the government debt, as the proponents of privatisation smugly state. Everything is being turned over to the theology of profit, and it only weakens the citizen’s ability to escape the almost-claustrophobic confines of capitalism. Only a small minority are actively mobilising and standing against these large transfers of wealth; for the remaining majority, on the other hand, austerity and privatisation are seen in a more contrived light, making them indifferent towards this marginalisation of the government. There are two main problems inherent in the process of consumerism. On the one hand it is responsible for socialising whole populations into insatiable consumers, to the detriment of the environment principally, but also (paradoxically) to the participatory individual per se. (Paradoxically because they are forever unfulfilled, as consumerism self-perpetuates itself. It also destroys social cohesion and places the self above others). Then, on the other hand, it encourages an unconscionable misallocation of resources, away from genuine needs to frivolous and inessential ones. This climate of repugnance towards the government makes itself apparent in the stance taken by consumers when income taxation is in discussion. Following an announcement for heightened tax rates, there will be an uproar of hostility emanating from the followers of consumerism. On the contrary, people have been spoon-fed the belief that reduced tax rates – from the richest to the poorest – will allow for more consumption-derived pleasure (Wolff, 2006). The irony in all this, of course, is that the animosity towards the government, and the demand for lower tax rates, will affect the populace adversely in the form of lower government spending and vitiated amenities. There is nothing democratic about consumerism; only those with the requisite wherewithal can realise and indulge in the practice. There is a parasitic, self-reinforcing relationship between this fixation of consumption and free-market ideology. Those who subscribe to the former may not necessarily subscribe to the latter; the chances are though, is that, in fact, they do. The opposite of free-market ideology – governmentalism – has connotations with more extractive tax-rates, and thus, by implication, a coercive appropriation of one’s purchasing power (Schneiderman, 1998). Their ability to consume, in turn, is eroded away, which creates a justification – in the eyes of the devout consumer – for minimal government interventionism. Notwithstanding the obvious benefits of redistributive-purposed taxation – to help the less fortunate – the dual forces of consumerism and individualism have reduced empathy and sympathy to atrophy.

Through the unremitting bombardment of advertising and marketing, the human mind, out of sheer capitulation to informational overload, inculcates the values of consumerism. To become a bona fide consumer one has to inculcate a fixation with their bodily appearance; how one looks is the sine qua non of consumerism. This self-consciousness of one’s appearance can be changed (or ostensibly improved) through consumptive behaviour, through the purchase of yet more ultimately needless commodities (Bauman Z. , 1983). It is a temporary palliative, a brief but quickly extinguished moment of satisfaction, which turns into longing and unhappiness. In a world where commodified items control the actions and behaviourisms of whole populations, the marginalised non-commodified avenues to contentedness – socially cohesive practices, which emphasis communality and interaction – are ignored and sidelined (Bauer et al., 2012). That consumerism is painted in such beautiful(ly idealistic) colours, people do not feel overly concerned with being exploited to the extent that they are. It is a necessary and tolerable unpleasantry to acquire their wage to partake in “the paradise of shopping” (Ivanova, 2011). People do not view commodities as the product of labour, but as mere commodities; they overlook the exertion that was instrumental in their creation, dehumanising these objects of any prior human contribution. It comes back to what, in Marxist terms, is known as commodity fetishism. Self-expression, a consciously creative notion, has been misappropriated by consumerism and turned into something that is manifested in what one wears. It is inevitably exclusionary, and those without the purchasing power (or increasingly who have reached their upper credit limit) are alienated from this consumption-driven spectacle. This idea can be encapsulated into the saying: “I am = what I have and what I consume” (Fromm, 1976) (p.36). Producers, with their impressive array of marketing mechanism, manipulate people into purchasing goods, commodities, of no intrinsic value. Indeed this change marks a transition away from the subjectification to objectification of the consumer; from individuals being subjects within the consumerist process, to constitutive cogs, mere objects. Producers have hijacked positive abstractions – "success," "sophistication," "hipness," "independence," etc., - into concrete realisations through the medium of consumption (Morris, 2001). The representative values of commodities are now ordered in terms of subjective significance, with extrinsic values subordinating intrinsic ones. It comes back to what French sociologist, Jean Baudrillard, described as the “political economy of the sign”, a society wherein the connotative values of a good has primacy over its actual use value. As consumers, we would choose a “trendy, fashionable pair of trainers”, over another pair of superior durability, comfortability, and affordability. Consumerism is construed as a readily available avenue to the valorisation of individualised identity. Because consumption is underpinned by this over-obsessive fascination with sign values – of what something symbolises - the chances of reappropriation are slim. Consumerism, like most important practices, has its very own culture and ideology – “a coherent set of practices, attitudes and values, based on advertising and the mass media but permeating the whole social structure, that encourages ever expanding consumption of consumer goods” (p.260). It was Italian Marxist Antonio Gramsci who famously formulated the notion of cultural hegemony, an instance in which the general populace assimilates the ruling party’s culture. On this qualification, therefore, consumerism can be seen as exhibiting hegemonic status. It is akin to a Ponzi scheme, a perpetual and hopeful game of creating new goods or services before the prior ones stultify.

To put a Marxist label on consumerism, and particularly its idiosyncratic culture-ideology, it would constitute a chunk of the superstructure (which is then constituted by a whole multitude of interactions, encouraging individuals, sometimes unwittingly, sometimes consciously, into the realm of consumerist “paradise”).  The process has also caught the attention of the Frankfurt School, with famous critical theorist, Herbert Marcuse, formulating the dichotomy of “true” or “false” needs, to distinguish between what is necessary, and what is merely desirable but inessential. From the above, it should hopefully be clear that the needs which consumerism depends on, which perpetuate its continuance, are the false ones. That the commodification of anything that is plausibly commodifiable is so successful, is because it brings about an extraneous and extrinsic satisfaction; it does not address intrinsic yearning, the wants that are of significance. To reiterate: consumerism is merely palliative, a soothing yet insufficient device to satisfy subproblems, the ones attached to the source of the discontentment. The fact consumerism is premised on the constant and unending consumption of materialistic items, may (though unlikely) be the cause of its undoing. Workers so fed-up with their ounce of purchasing power will demand, more and more ferociously, greater and greater wages, in the end creating the fermenting conditions for a working class revolt. And this isn’t just exaggerated scaremongering. This very situation – a proletarian revolution – was documented, in waves, during the year of 1989 across Eastern Europe (Bauman Z. , 1992) (p.170).

Psychology and consumerism pretty much go hand in hand. How the brain functions is important for the success and sustainment of consumerism. When our ‘biological needs’ are satisfied (to steal a phrase from Maslow’s hierarchy of needs), new desires are created, which are increasingly orientated towards materialist possessions. An iterative cycle of “dream, desire, acquisition, and disillusionment” is spawned (Migone, 2007), whereby consumers experience infatuation towards a particular good, only for unfulfillment to kick-in after purchase. In a society where the individual is most important, there is a need to openly exhibit one’s status. That there just happens to be an ideological force as consumerism which fits the criterion for this exhibition of individualism is suspiciously coincidental. Advertising is no longer restricted to aesthetics, but has moved into the psychological realm; it prizes itself in its ability to entrap the sensory neurons in the brain, those little receptors which light up ecstatically if prompted by something visually and psychologically appealing. In other words, advertising depends on the manipulation, both consciously and subliminally, of emotions (Cahill, 2001). The misery of others has been overexposed to such an extent that people are now desensitised to these systemic problems (a worrisome thought in itself). We don’t find homelessness emotive anymore, but new avant-garde fads; this, increasingly, is the only time emotion emerges to the fore. Emotionless as a population, the term post-emotionalism has been coined, to describe a society in which emotion is only evoked by artificial, not natural, stimuli; where “synthetic, quasi-emotions become the basis for widespread manipulation by self, others, and the culture industry as a whole” (p.14) (Mestrovic, 1997)Marketing specialists understand the basics of how the human brain functions, and more importantly what triggers its stimulation. It is these triggers that are being activated by marketing ploys in order to compel an impulsive purchase (Behr, 2010). Hunger being one example of these triggers, a fact that has not gone unnoticed by food producers. To artificially stimulate the viewer’s brain, into an impromptu desire for food – their actual hunger notwithstanding – promotions now use subliminal messages to instigate this reaction. As a process, consumerism is funny for the fact that it turns out-of-reach luxuries, one day, into necessitates, the next (Gummer and Goldsmith 2007: 41). Instrumental to this necessitation is the clever but manipulative psychologically-driven marketing techniques of entities who are responsible for the never-ending supply of consumer items – profit-hungry corporations and their equally as profit-hungry shareholders. A Frankfurt School perspective pairs mass culture – i.e. consumerism – with mass deception; of how consumption is antithetical to true liberation and autonomy – the very thing it promises to provide. Through a joint effort between advertisers and the media, this falsity has been systematised and reinforced until an uncritical acceptance prevails. From an early age, the collective tabula rasa of millions of children is socialised into one in which consumerism is considered the norm, something ordinary. To expand on this point about advertising, there is a clear and positive relationship between overexposure to marketing and consumerism. We have identified consumption as a process which provides gratification, something that allows the consumer to temporarily forget about the dissatisfaction of the workplace. It is an effective device at diverting attention away from the capitalist system, away from questioning its morality, its fairness, its inclusiveness. These two environments – the consumer and working milieux – depend on one another for their continued existence. The ease by which the wage-provider can justify a small wage is, in part, because of consumerism. To venture into the hedonistic paradise of consumption, the employee is willing to accept any wage. That is one half of the duality. The other half – how working perpetuates consumerism – relates closely to the prior point about tiny remuneration. If the worker only has little disposable income, the entry into the perfectionistic consumerist world can only ever be infrequently. What I mean to say, more straight-to-the-point-ly, is that the worker does not experience any significant diminishing marginal returns. If everybody were filthy rich, then consumerism would quickly become sucked of any excitement it once had, into a void of mundanity.

Conspiracy theories are typically laughed away as not being worthy of rebuttal. But some, indeed this one, are worth considering. Thinking about how low wages are prolonged one begins to question why are they so depressed; the economy is growing, so why is this not reflected in rising wages? This leads me to believe that low wages are artificially (though subtly) preserved by those with vested interests. What justification do I have for this claim? Nothing but simple intuitive reasoning. As the economy acclimatised into the suffocating climate of neoliberalism, there was a reorientation in policy: what became important was financial services, not the traditional backbone of any economy, manufacturing. With this growing dependence on financialisation the economy was flooded with cheap credit, which at a time when consumption underpinned by debt became  condonable (coincidence?), encouraged people into indebtedness. Once this choice was made, and those with a perfect credit record gave up this pristine status for that of a debtor, people were entrapped, legally, within the capitalist system. They have a reason to behave and be an exemplar to all others seeking to be a emotionless citizen; debt negates the inner feelings of dissent.

The next point requires citing yet another French sociologist, Emile Durkheim, who wrote extensively on the relationship of society and individuals, on the one hand, and society and communities, on the other. What he found was that within an individualistic society, and even more so in one that emphasises money (i.e. under capitalism), social relations degenerate from their seemingly irreducible natural state to a less organic, even inorganic, form. To recalibrate the disorientation of society, consumption as a leisurely process was introduced. Those that were on the verge of, or suffering from, anomie found purpose again in life; to become a proud and pious consumer. Consumerism has only built upon its initial strength, to establish itself as something that is taken as normal, so normal in fact that to renounce consumption is to create grounds for one’s marginalisation (Migone, 2007). It is this aspect – of how those that are indifferent towards consumerism consume regardless, in fear of marginalisation – that could go some way to explaining the intensity by which people have chosen to enslave themselves to credit. Income inequality is one of the major 21st century problems, alongside an ecological crisis and scarily unpredictable geopolitical tensions (more so the former, though). The attention that income inequality ought to warrant, for its severity and damaging implications, is evidently nowhere close in reality. People do not necessarily turn a blind eye to the problem, but are content with the current trend as long as their access to consumerism is not precipitously curbed. In this post-Fordist and globalised world, labour markets have been deeply restructured to take account for the flexible needs of producers. Workforces hold little bargaining power when it comes to wage discussions; which at a time when job insecurity is rising, along with longer working hours, is a lamentable sight. That consumerism is predicated upon the commodification of practically everything, in this respect, it is highly reductionist; it reduces everything to the level of the commodity (Beabout & Echeveria, 2002). The entry into the consumerist sphere is only permitted on the strict condition that one has the sufficient wherewithal; to acquire this wherewithal, of course, one has to work; and by working one is essentially exchanging their labour power for, in effect, an admission ticket into this shopping wonderland. Between this relationship exists a paradox: the worker is trying with all their effort and determination to realise that feeling of liberation which consumerism ‘brings’, but at the same time, is made ever more dependent and subjugated to their wage-provider.

Liberty, the brother of individualism, places a heavy emphasis on the individual, and their self-sustaining powers. Ever since feudalism, when classical thinkers such as John Locke and Thomas Hobbes wrote their treatises on liberalism and the invasive state, liberty has been accorded more and more value. Of course some question whether this liberty is indeed for everybody, or just for the wealthy; is it one standard for all, or merely a subtle instance of double standards? It is a point that Marx and Engels found to be true: ‘from the moment when individual property can no longer be transformed into bourgeois property, from that moment, you say, individuality vanishes. You must, therefore, confess that by “individual” you mean no other person than the bourgeois’ (Marx & Friedrich, 1848). Marx was no denialist when it came to whether individuality was present in society; he accepted this fact. It was to whom, or rather to what, this individuality was assigned that he was sceptical of. Capital, Marx believed, was the only thing with true individuality; to capture capital (and become a capitalist) was therefore the only possible route to individuality. Without capital one has to offer their labour to a capitalist, thus forfeiting individuality and autonomy. In this era, government played an important but minimalist role: to maintain a relation were the employer can employ workers freely, and employees can choose employment freely. There was a certain freedom in their behaviour, workers were not coerced into a place of work. But when the choice of employment ranged from being fully exploited to slightly less so, what this revered freedom bought was drudgery and toil. There are means to overcome this vulnerability, namely to unionise together and demand a higher wage. But even unionisation was to compromise individual freedom – on the side of the capitalist; they would no longer hold the ability to dictate and set an appropriate price tag (in their eyes) on labour. In the times that these debates were first sparred, and indeed also today, when liberal individualism is once again pervasive, if the government was to (mis?)appropriate the wealth of capitalists it would be derided as an attack on one’s inalienable freedom. This was until John S Mill postulated his views on individualism and, specifically, the permissibility of the capitalist to accumulate and accumulate wealth. At this juncture Mills diverged away from the (by now) conventional truisms, highlighting the unfairness of how the capitalist contributes very little but feels entitled to such substantial remuneration; ‘independently of any trouble or outlay incurred by themselves. They grow richer, as it were in their sleep, without working, risking, or economizing’ (Mill, 2004) (p.220). By merely owning the factors of production the capitalist was able to, not out of his own wit, intellect, or perseverance,  extract the surplus value from their overworked labour force; indeed this surplus value came to be known as ‘unearned income’. Mills, to the disgust of fellow liberals, was sympathetic towards the appropriation of capital from capitalists, if it clearly derived from ‘unearned income’. The argument was that, if the capitalist is merely profiting from their monopoly price or because they own the factors of production, and in turn benefits from ‘unearned income’, they are not actually qualified to accumulate this wealth (O'Flynn, 2012). The problematic nature of individualism stems from the fact that, when everybody thinks and acts in solely their self-interest, individual rights and liberties are given primacy while duties and responsibilities are attenuated and neglected (Passini, 2013). Conflicts quickly arise between what is optimal for the individual, on the one hand, and what is optimal for others, on the other. All that matters is one’s individuality, and its improvement. Opportunities may indeed present themselves, to assist others in their quest of realising individuality, but despite the altruistic satisfaction from these acts of benevolence, they are ignored and avoided.

Does this theory push the bounds of realism too far, or is it reflective of reality?

While writing this piece it did strike me, not once but on a number of occasions, about whether the theory and critiques of consumerism are just the paranoid ramblings of some past anti-capitalist; whose thought processes were preprogramed to blame the capitalist system for all societal problems. Is this self-perpetuating circle of consume, unfulfillment, on a constant repeat cycle representative of the real world? People may not admit to behaving in this mechanistic manner, as it will appear imperceptibly to them; this imperceptibility is after all the beauty of modern day advertisement. That is not to deny the existence of this circulatory cycle, just that it will be expressed in more agreeable terms, that will go by unnoticed and not warrant a second glance. If people consciously knew they were being patronised and tricked into purchasing items that will, at some later point, become undesirable, then encouraging consumption in the first place would become an impossible task. What first comes to mind are fads and fashions. Indeed the motion by which consumption trends goes along in concert with the latest fads and fashions would suggest this analysis to be correct. Ask somebody do they follow these short-lived fads, and the likelihood of a yes is much higher than when asked are they manipulated by their favourite clothing designers. Importantly, though, they are both synonymous, and by answering yes to second question, they are, albeit indirectly, answering yes to the first one too.

Consumerism and the environment together just does not work. In fact attempting to reconcile the differences between the two is tantamount to assuaging the restiveness of two hyperactive and obstinate children who both want the same thing; there is no compromise. To protect the environment, consumers need to internalise the values of sustainability and ethicality. But these conflict with what consumerism espouses: an endless excess of consumption. In the end it comes down to one question: as an intelligent species do we care and value for environment the most, or that pair of trainers over there? The answer, as far as I see it, is self-evident; but then again, in an individualised society there is a disconnection between one’s actions and the wider implications upon the environment. That this mode of thinking pervades the consumerist society makes this important task particularly (though not insurmountably) difficult.

To draw this discussion to a close it is worthwhile to touch on the effects of an individualistic, consumerist society. Instead of valuing people for their non-materialistic virtues – their personality, their morality, their altruism – people regulate their human interaction in terms of what one wears, drives, or even how one looks. And given the selectivity with where nudism is permitted, there is no alternative to a clothes-cladded society. That people judge others on these superficial and largely unrepresentative variables is typical of the quintessential consumer in today’s world. Only by putting these what amount to pointless and pretentious differences aside will a more integrative, empathetic and sympathetic society arise. Until then, expect more narcissism, selfishness, and general disregard for other people – including yourself (sorry!).

If you enjoyed what you've just read, could you be so kind as to press the g+1 a little further down. It means I will appear closer to the first page when somebody types, for example, a related search into Google, which given the fact I rely wholly on Facebook groups would be massively helpful for exposure. :)

Works Cited

  1. Bauer et al., M. A. (2012). Cuing Consumerism: Situational Materialism Undermines Personal and Social Well-Being. Psychological Science, 23(5), 517-523.
  2. Bauman, Z. (1983). Industrialism, Consumerism and Power. Theory, Culture & Society, 1(3), 32-43.
  3. Bauman, Z. (1992). Communism: A Postmortem. In Intimations of Postmodernity.
  4. Beabout, G. R., & Echeveria, E. J. (2002). The Culture of Consumerism: A Catholic and Personalist Critique. Journal of Markets & Morality, 5(2), 339–383.
  5. Behr, R. (2010). Anti-consumerism. Public Policy Research, 17(3), 123-129.
  6. Bocock, R. (1993). Consumption.
  7. Cahill, M. (2001). The Implications of Consumerism for the Transition to a Sustainable Society. Social Policy & Administration, 35(5), 627-639.
  8. Campbell, D. (1989). The romantic ethic and the spirit of modern consumerism.
  9. Fischer, C. S. (2008). Paradoxes of American Individualism. Sociological Forum, 23(2), 363-372.
  10. Fromm, E. (1976). To have or to be?
  11. Halman, L. (1996). Individualism in Individualized Society? Results from the European Value Surveys. International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 37(3), 195-214.
  12. Huang, J. J., Huang, M. Y., & Syu, F. K. (2010). Liberated anomie in generation next: Hyperindividualism, extreme consumerism, and social isolationism. Fooyin Journal of Health Sciences, 2(2), 41-47.
  13. Ivanova, M. N. (2011). Consumerism and the Crisis: Wither ‘the American Dream’? Critical Sociology, 37(3), 329-350.
  14. Lehrer, K. (2001). Individualism, Communitarianism and Consensus. The Journal of Ethics, 5(2), 105-120.
  15. Marx, K., & Friedrich, E. (1848). The Communist Manifesto.
  16. Mestrovic, S. (1997). Post Emotional Society.
  17. Migone, A. (2007). Hedonistic Consumerism: Patterns of Consumption in Contemporary Capitalism. Review of Radical Political Economics, 2, 173-200.
  18. Mill, J. S. (2004). Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy: Abridged.
  19. Morris, M. (2001). Contradictions of Post-modern Consumerism and Resistance. Studies in Political Economy, 64, 7-32.
  20. Mulgan, G. (1994). Connexity.
  21. O'Flynn, M. (2012). Capital Accumulation and the Historical Decline of Liberal Individualism. Critical Sociology, 39(4), 493-509.
  22. Passini, S. (2013). A binge-consuming culture: The effect of consumerism on social interactions in western societies. Culture & Psychology, 19(3), 369-390.
  23. Schneiderman, D. (1998). Constitutionalizing the Culture-Ideology of Consumerism. Social Legal Studies, 7(2), 213-238.
  24. Wolff, R. D. (2006). Ideological State Apparatuses, Consumerism, and U.S. Capitalism: Lessons for the Left. Rethinking Marxism: A Journal of Economics, Culture & Society, 17(2), 223-235.
  25. Wuthnow, R. (1991). Acts of compassion.

Thursday 4 September 2014

Income inequality: the growing parallel between the rich and poor.

Introduction

In the UK at the time of writing, there appears to be a handful of issues that are seemingly inexpungible from the media limelight; they are tireless and of unceasing appeal. Immigration and welfare benefit frauds, to take just two examples, are both fanatically and continually publicised. Just open up a copy of the Daily Mail and observe the outstanding triviality of the chosen topics - the latest drivel about X Factor, Big Brother, or my personal guilty pleasure, I'm a Celebrity...Get Me Out of Here!, no doubt. What goes under the radar, so to speak, and is of far more importance than the aforementioned topics is the problem of income inequality. As an illustration to how important it is, the above topics of immigration and welfare benefit frauds both pale in significance; each can be readily addressed (that is, if you truly believe them to be pressing issues) and neither affects the entire population, from the millionaire to the "benefit scrounger". Some publications do indeed report the scary extent of uneven income distribution – but these are often read exclusively by individuals who are already aware of the problem, not the masses of people who are not. This is strange and, to a degree, paradoxical, considering the abundance of exemplifications; inequalities of income are to be found within all major Western nations, emerging countries, and developing countries; in fact, it would be a fair analysis to state the entire world (at least the parts inhabited by humans) as being beset by income inequality. As such, the following is written with income inequality, and this alone in mind; written in an attempt at providing the reader with an insightful introductory text to the phenomenon. That it goes underreported is not because media disseminators view the topic as unengaging or unlucrative. Rather, the true reason is because of the monopolisation of the industry, because only a few individuals own the major media corporations. And it is these same individuals, incidentally, who have not only their interests at heart (which makes them not completely selfish), but also their elitist buddies – about the only people who are content with the current state of affairs – and nobody else. There are of course exceptions, but in large part the choice and diversity of newspapers is controlled by the same individuals. To quote Malcolm X, who I believe embodies this point in a single statement: "The media's the most powerful entity on earth. They have the power to make the innocent guilty and to make the guilty innocent, and that's power. Because they control the minds of the masses”. The crude analogy of the 99% and 1% that frequently crops up in the income inequality discourse is not an exaggeration; if anything, it is a representative comparison, and helps to illuminate the issue to an extent.  In what proceeds, I will courageously present a multifaceted account of income inequality, from its origins in the 20th and 21st centuries, to what causes it; from the reasons of why it is so worrying and disconcerting, to the solutions we have at our disposal to tackle the problem. It is with the historical timeline that I begin – so if it is provocation you want you may be disappointed (that is, until section three, then it truly gets exciting).

History

Income inequality has not always been a problem (since the first Gilded Age anyway). Only relatively recently has a disparity emerged again – for a precise date, or thereabouts, the initial set of seeds were sown in the latter half of the 1970s. Prior to this era, incomes across the board were tolerable and fair; importantly, there was no unacceptable gulf between the rich and poor. Capitalism, though disputed by some, was and continues to be the underlying engine for economic growth. The developed world and, to a lesser extent, the developing world would not be at their current stages of development was it not for one of capitalism’s main virtues, the profit motive. Competition between voraciously profit-hungry businesses prompts exciting innovations, bringing new products to the consumer’s living room and once-dreamlike services. Investment was committed with a long-term perspective, putting faith in a budding and hopeful business. Everyone was the beneficiary of this form of capitalism. Consumers remained happy by a perennial introduction of original goods and services, investors were kept contented by their consistently modest returns, and businesses saw profits rise year-on-year. Most important, stability remained buoyant – the textbook spikes and nosedives of the business cycle were not a huge issue. How this has changed. Today, investment is recognised as a route to quick but unsatisfying returns. No recognition is given to the long-term health and vitality of the business – profit trumps all other considerations.

Working harmoniously until the 1970s, the money economy, fuelled and driven by the rapacious motives of financial bankers, and the productive economy, encompassing all factories that churn out consumer durables and services, have become increasingly polarised. While the meteoric rise of the money economy has extended the influence of bankers and financers on both an economic and political platform, the productive economy is in a worsening condition, shrinking in both size and importance. One of the first fundamental lessons of economics is that prosperity, in large part, is underpinned by consumer bolstered demand. That being said, a continuation of the severe misallocation of income we are seeing today, from the majority to minority, will effectively curb such consumption - how does one pay for goods and services if their income has been decimated to an amount barely sufficient of simple sustenance?

After the Great Depression, one would surely expect the governments of the world to isolate and analyse the many causes and as a reassurance to the general public, put in place the desperately needed safety nets to ensure a reoccurrence of such a gloomy downturn is impossible at best and improbable at worst. In fact, worries were indeed appeased – a plethora of policies were drawn up and accordingly administered. Reinforced by these responsive policies to the Great Depression, a sweeping redistribution of income took place; the nauseating bonuses and rewards of the super-rich were curtailed in; favourable taxes towards the rich became untenable, begrudgingly handing over a greater proportion of their salaries to the taxman due to more progressive tax rates. The populace itself held the rich in contempt. Widespread was an overarching attitude, to be later turned into policy that the millionaires of the age were undeservingly wealthy. Complementary measures, too, were rolled out – in particular, monopolies were coercively disbanded in order to promote competition. These policies were successful in their purpose; income inequality did indeed fall, and by a considerable amount. 


In fact, this period of startlingly equality was known as the Great Compression in the United States. Similarly, in the UK commentators dubbed this period of equalisation as the “great levelling”. The number of UK based millionaires fell from a plateau of more than 1000 to a low of 36. As soon became palpably clear, this virtuous cycle of fairer income distribution was to be a brief respite from the vices of extreme income inequality. Statistically, the wealth held by the top one percent shrunk diminutively between 1937 to 1978, from 12.6 per cent to 4.2 per cent of national income. On the advent of the 21st century 4.2 per cent had incrementally risen to 10 per cent mark of national income, tentatively behind the peak of the Great Depression. By the doing of Margaret “Maggie” Thatcher, the UK government was metamorphosed into a destructive machine hell-bent on the complete obliteration of intransigent trade unions. A success in the eyes of Thatcher, the bargaining power of workers did indeed fall, putting a limit on their clout and influence when discussing wage increases. In the end, the unions conceded defeat; their wages, the very reason for the strikes and demonstrations, remained stagnant, not rising proportionately with profit; and as if to afflict more humiliation upon them, the pay of senior staff members gratuitously rocketed. This poses the chilling question: once the wants and needs of the rich are temporarily satisfied, what is to be done with the surplus output that no one but the rich can afford? The answer: debt – and lots of it. To retain a vestige of purchasing power, working class families went down the precarious and dangerous path of indebtedness. For a short while, the debt-fuelled consumption binge was a source of economic prosperity – economic prosperity with an artificial tint to it.

At around the same time, the US presidential election had come around again. After a close counting of the votes, not without controversy, George Bush was to be instated as the new president. Shortly after his inauguration, Bush wasted no time in perpetuating the policies of his predecessor Ronald Regan, espousing a constellation of freer markets, smaller government and lower taxes. In the economic profession, passivity pervaded almost all major economists, accepting unhesitatingly the claims by the conservatives that inequality was a necessary precondition to a more productive and faster growing economy. Heterodoxical as ever, eminent economist Paul Krugman believed otherwise and publicly opposed conventional policy and questioned the merits of ‘Reagonomics’. Unwilling to acknowledge Krugman’s contentions with epistemological judgement, the conservatives were obstinately dismissive, arguing that although income inequality was on the rise it had in fact paradoxically liberated poorer individuals; liberated in the sense of laying out more viable routes to ascend the societal hierarchy, to higher echelons. On the subject of retorts, another personal favourite of the rich and their community is calling upon the classic and far from perfect trickle-down theory. (This theory has become so prominent that it has acquired its own compartmentalisation in economics, known as “Trickle-down economics”). At its core is the fiercely contested premise of cutting top income tax rates in order to engender this so-called trickle-down effect; and, it is hoped, in doing so a notable rise in investment will prevail, as the rich have more money to fund new projects and initiate more positive multiplier effects within the economy. This, of course, is conjecture and far from guaranteed; and indeed saving or more deleterious investments are often opted for instead. These are not just speculations, either – peer-reviewed research confirms a strong and positive relationship between income and one’s marginal propensity to save (that is, how much of one’s income is apportioned to savings). In other words, as one becomes more rich, there is a tendency to save a larger proportion of income. Moreover, why are the rich in particular so deserving of these tax cuts? Why not bestow the poor majority with these tax cuts, whom will almost certainly purchase more goods and services? Of course, the tenuousness of arguing in sympathy of income inequality is made even more insignificant, even more insupportable, when placed in juxtaposition against the mounting abundance of scholarly evidence affirming the extremity of income inequality. A longitudinal data diligently complied by French economists Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, for example, tracked the income concentration of the top 1 percent in the United States from 1913 to 2006. What they discovered was that at two instances within this period the top 1 percent held over a fifth of national income; the first, notably, was in the latter half of the 1920s, preceding the notorious Great Depression; the second, similarly, occurred at the beginning of the 21st century, a short number of years before the so-called Great Recession of 2008-09. It is known for people to mistake causality, but such a refutation is insufficient here – a highly skewed income distribution is a principal cause of shockingly egregious crises. The top 0.01 alone had 5% of national income (see graph below). The fact that indebtedness proliferated in both of these intervals, cannot be attributed to mere coincidence, either. 


Tantamount to a neoliberal conceding people have irrational tendencies (for non-economists, a cardinal theory of Neoliberalism is that all people demonstrate rational expectations; in other words, all people are rational), Alan Greenspan, a partisan of all things free market, admitted that the United States did indeed have an income inequality problem, and that exacerbation had made it too consequential to be ignored. In 2007, a mere two years later, Greenspan’s replacement, Ben Bernanke, reiterated the same point, recognising income inequality as being at an acute degree.

Once dominant values of the time, parsimony and conservatism discouraged indebtedness. As these values underwent a fundamental transformation, now in full effect, the practise of borrowing became the norm. All around was a façade of prosperity; people drove about in new-off-the-production-line vehicles, wore once atypical designer brands, and left the country on a frequent basis to enjoy exotic holidays. Indeed, all this pretentiousness and wealth was illusory; undergirding all the consumption and profligacy was a mountainous pile of debt. In 1993, outstanding personal debt of UK citizens totalled £574 billion; fast-forward less than two decades, and this amount now stood at £1400 billion in 2008. “An important political response to inequality was populist credit expansion, which allowed people the consumption possibilities that their stagnant income otherwise would not support”, to quote Raghuram Rajan, the Governor of the Reserve Bank of India and eminent professor.


Before an immersive exploration into the depths of today's inequality is commenced, it is worthwhile to succinctly recap the aftermath of the Great Depression. It was manifestly clear a society controlled by nothing but the whimsical free market was bound to failure. Greed, avarice and self-interest, would you believe it, cause irrational tendencies. Fortunately, a prominent economist by the name John Maynard Keynes came to the fore and expounded a set of ideas. The end result: Keynesian economics. A sceptic of an unfettered market economy, Keynes suggested an alternative, one at complete variance to the economic orthodoxy of the day. In short, what he advocated was for a sort of paternalistic relationship between the government and market; the government being the rule-maker of the two. It would be the government’s role, and in its interest, therefore, to monitor and keep a close eye on market activities. An excerpt took out of one of Keynes’s innumerable writings explains the situation; 'The decadent international but individualistic capitalism in the hands of which we found ourselves after the war is not a success. It is not intelligent. It is not beautiful. It is not just. It is not virtuous. And it doesn't deliver the goods. In short we dislike it, and we are beginning to despise it.' Indeed, the policies Keynes espoused worked better than anyone could have expected. So much so that between 1950 and 1973 world growth soared - a period known historically as 'the Golden Age'.

Outside of the UK, a contagion was spreading, the ripples of which were reaching UK shores. In fervent debate around academic circles was a contention about the government – the question often posed was; why have the government conduct the role of market when it was not as efficient? It was a volte-face of the most radical proportions. With only vestiges of credibility left, Keynesian economics was condemned to an eternity of apparent failure, being swiftly ousted, to be replaced by the paragon of all things free market, Neoliberalism. Advocated by an intelligentsia under the guise of the Mont Perlerin Society, the prescribed policies were purposefully designed to widen the free market – and, contrary to Keynes, limit the involvement, (or rather interference, depending on one’s economic stance), of the government in market-based outcomes. Founded by the prominent Austrian economist Friedrich August von Hayek, and including Milton Friedman at this particular time, the society mesmerised the two leaders of the United States and UK at the time – Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Kegan – into believing the potential of free market fundamentalism. It took on an alluring reputation of being the be-all and end-all solution to economic woes. To intervene and cause a distortion in market-based outcomes was to make one guilty of stupidity; it had only one inevitability: the dilution of efficiency. Accordingly, any policies or entities that did exactly this, irrespective of supposed importance or size, were quickly disbanded. Entrepreneurialism at the time was in a state of sluggishness. A curtailment in tax rates, it was believed, would act as a stimulative measure. Alongside this, a meritocracy culture, championed by Thatcher, was emerging across the UK, in which ability was made the primary determinant of wealth and societal status.

In the mid part of the 1970s a selection of events, some more so than others, contributed to a general deterioration in competitiveness among the G-7 countries – reflected by the falling profit margins within their manufacturing industries. Struggling to remain afloat, the fact union militancy was particularly intense only aggravated the situation. The incessant wage demands were simply not feasible, irreconcilable with declining profits. In this regard, therefore, it became a necessity for companies to slash the going wage rate, lest cashflow problems and potential bankruptcy. Indeed, this is exactly what happened – employees had to endure a cutback in their pay, albeit as contingent to their employment and respective company’s survival. But in a matter of years profits had burgeoned back to pre-crisis levels and remained buoyant. Now that companies had found a secure financial grounding, one would expect a corresponding increase in the wage rate. However, as is often the case in money-driven situations, greed trumped equity and company executives opted for the contrary – that is, a calcification of the already stagnant wage rate, whilst awarding those with seniority status inordinate pay packages. This is not a sustainable strategy – in fact, signs of a productivity-wage gap are becoming more and more pronounced, problematic for the reason that it is a clear indication of supply outstripping demand, a known cause of deflation.

Transitioning from managed capitalism to unadulterated market capitalism, the belief that markets are efficient and self-regulating was given unstinting credence by outright biased economists. Privatisation was popularised, both in debate and in practise. As was the scaling back of regulatory policies. Unions were viewed as a superfluous interest group, always unsatisfied with relatively higher wages and forever demanding more. This unsatisfiability was performed to such a large extent that it provided the impetus to the outbreaks of stagflation (an economic condition whereby both inflation and unemployment simultaneously rise) in the 1970s.  That is not to say union militancy was the only impetus, as that would be untrue. It could in fact be argued to have been of secondary significance. What commentators have a recurring tendency to omit is how the intense inflationary pressure was not wholly attributable to the spiralling wage demands, ignoring the significant OPEC crisis in its entirety. In spite of these exogenous oil shocks, Thatcher carried on, even accelerated, her personal and spiteful vendetta against the unions. British unionised workers had employment rights abolished, wage councils discontinued, and strikes became more onerous. Between 1979 and 2009, UK trade union membership plummeted from 13.5 million to 6.7 million. Stagflation was no doubt in part to blame for the sudden obsession, bordering on delirium, with inflation. Economic targets were reprioritised - inflation, rather than unemployment, took precedent. It was a cause of such unbearably grieve, that Thatcher and her loyal servants employed a harsh but effective double-sided policy: fiscal conservatism coupled with a tightening monetary policy, in an attempt to tame the recalcitrant inflation. Eventually, inflation started to drop to more manageable levels – but not without the accompaniment of harmful and lasting side effects. In retrospect, on looking at the results of the policy – relatively lower inflation – and the pain and suffering caused – vast unemployment – it questions whether it was the most desirable decision. Enveloped by a demand-deficient induced recession, unemployment reached soaring levels. Policymakers anticipated an increase in unemployment and believed it to be transitory – the slump, it was purported, was a temporary precondition to a more prosperous economy. So when the unemployment prolonged and affected some areas disproportionately, it came as an unexpected shock to those in power. Deindustrialisation was induced yet more quickly by a rearrangement of exchange rate controls (from a relatively fixed to floating exchange rate), the result of which was a sudden, large strengthening of the pound, so to embrace the sentiment of globalisation and its ethos. No longer subservient to governmental demands, exchange rates moved, or floated rather, in accordance to the laws of supply and demand. The subjugation of inflation was further intensified by revising interest rates upwards, to a percentage deemed as excessive in the eyes of export-led firms. Naturally, an inundation of foreign capital entered the country, all raring to partake in the game of interest rate differentials, a ramification that was welcomed by financiers, but detested and hopelessly resisted by manufacturers. In the end, traditional companies that in days gone by had been the central pillar of the economy, the primary driver of the industrial revolution, began to sink down to the murky depths of bankruptcy and insolvency, burdened under the drastic curtailments in international trade.

How inflation appeared through Thatcher's distorted vision.
Neoliberal ideology, so prominent and authoritative at this point in history, was encapsulated into policy under the Washington Consensus. As part of the Washington Consensus, liberalisation in both trade and financial services was strongly advocated - and, indeed, this is what was prescribed, in significant dosage. (Funnily enough, this same liberalisation was imposed upon a number of struggling emerging economies, who, as a direct result of this forceful recommendation, experienced severe economic turmoil; just note the South American countries crises, for example). Between Wall Street and London was a competitive ferocity at the verge of boiling point. To try and attain the upper-hand, so to speak, Thatcher implemented an almost comprehensive round of deregulation, known by the fitting nickname, “Big Bang”. Then, as the Conservative party lost out to Labour in the national elections, the carefree financers were full of dread and anxiousness, anticipating a more uptight and regulative imposition upon their activities. So when such an anticipation failed to materialise, an audible huff of relieve could be heard across the City. In fact, Tony Blair, the newly instated prime minister, viewed the secretive nature of the bankers as permissible. Blair’s insouciance was primarily reasoned to the ascendant nature of the financial community. Prior to the 2008 crisis the stock market, a mechanism where even the average Joe can invest into a few well-known companies and expect a fruitful return with optimism, was to be a centre of hubristic behaviour. The media constructed a fanciful caricature of how a simple investment can make one into a millionaire. People gullibly believed such stories and jumped on the figurative bandwagon. Professional investors, too, supposedly adept in the art of investment, were beguiled by the individualistic, short-term approach. Not even a PHD from Harvard guaranteed immunity. Self-aggrandizement was the order of the day.

Financial institutions were subject to ceaseless inflows and outflows of money, on an expedition to safety away from the encroaching hands of the taxman. Shares were bought and sold in quick succession, with little thought given to the fundamental value of the company. The sheer rapidity in which the trades of these financial instruments took place, a large part of which were of a speculative and inherently unstable nature, was to be a predominant, though not exclusive, cause of destabilisation for some businesses. In vogue was the practise of taking over unsuspecting companies, often with hostility, to be forced through a process of downsizing (through extensive redundancies), all to attain a semblance of efficiency. Whether the company truly becomes more efficient is questionable. The main winners from this ruthless practise were shareholders and the new owners – not, emphasis, the current workforce. In spite of these superficial “efficiency gains”, shareholders were so keen, so bloodthirsty to make a profit that they bid up the companies share value regardlessly. This suited the new owners brilliantly – once the share value reached a price above that originally paid by a significant margin, ownership was abdicated and equity sold, and they wander off with a handsome profit.

The first signs of inequality were gaugeable from the share of national income being paid to employees in the form of earnings – what this indictor unequivocally showed, was that a gradual decline was in process. Of course, there are some stakeholders, notably greedier than others and demand more than their fair share of the profit. In turn, a hotbed for conflicts is spawned; investors, owners, employees – each demanding an increasingly bigger pay-out from a finite pot of money. The major loser since the 1970s has been employees; inflation has outrun wage increases, reducing real income implicitly. Left to its own accord the capitalist system will encourage a continuation of this distribution and exacerbate the already significant income gap between the poor and rich. Indeed, as paradoxically as it may sound differentiated incomes are in fact a desirable characteristic for an economy to demonstrate. Too equal, in that profits are shared among all stakeholders indiscriminately, and companies will find themselves undercapitalised, unable to pursue and capitalise on investment opportunities. Too unequal, in that profit is greedily horded by the owners, and the purchasing power of the masses will stagnate and ultimately decline. (The major Western countries would constitute the latter description, and are leaning too far in this direction). Of course, this is not to say an unequal distribution is a path to economic utopia – rather, a modest illustration of inequality is accommodative of a properly functioning economy. Clearly, both outcomes are unenviable, and as a compromise, a combination of the two is necessary – that is, neither too equal nor too unequal.

Income inequality is of benefit to a tiny cohort of individuals only. Financiers and chief executive officers (CEOs), to take two examples, are beneficiaries of inequality. With year-on-year pay rises on average ofSE 11 percent between 1999 and 2006, CEOs are firmly in the minority of employees unaffected by the erosive effect of inflation. The remaining employees, on the other hand, are not quite as financially comfortable; unlike their ultimate senior, pay rose for this majority by an average of 1.4 per cent between the same time frame. In 2006, amid the irrational exuberance of financiers, the top 100 CEOs earned almost 100 times that of their average employee. Interestingly, the hedge fund managers, CEOs, and financiers, the individuals earning these ludicrous sums, are part of the private sector exclusively. Profit is so alluringly powerful that efficiency – or what is perceived as efficient – is derived to a larger extent than government-owned organisations, who operate under the veil of public welfare maximisation.

Until now, income inequality has been described strictly in the context of the developed world, within the Anglo-American countries. Let this not detract from the importance of talking about emerging and developing countries, not least for the influential role they will play in forthcoming decades. For these countries, in some cases, income inequality is even more of a problem than within the US and UK. Often, the economy is undergoing a painful ideological transition, from communism or socialism to capitalism. Since the Cold War, any grounds for taking communism seriously as an ideology have lost any credibility and conviction; any glimmers of hope that communism would bring about a functional, prosperous economy have dissipated. (Only questionably sane ideologues still argue otherwise, and are often found in the outlandish nations such as North Korea). Instead, countries began to experiment cautiously with the virtues of capitalism. As part of this change, privatisation was performed on a nationwide basis. As a process, privatisation is a perfect opportunity for well-connected individuals to ascend instantly to millionaire status. Auctions (with questionable legitimacy) decide whose hands the public services end up in, and how much for. Such was the case for Russia in the 90s, these public services were sold at a fraction of their true value as underhanded political favours. They decide who becomes an oligarch and who does not. Chile is a single exemplar of widespread income inequality; while the top fifth of the population own 67 per cent of national income, the bottom fifth barely survives on an indigent 3 per cent. Globally, too, income inequality is at an absurd level. Unsettling to say the least, a statistic that came to light recently found the combined wealth of the world’s poorest 2.5 billion (or about 35% of the entire global population) to be at equivalence with the top 1000 wealthiest individuals (or about 0.00001377841% of the world population). Still, there remain some individuals, though dwindling in numbers, who view nothing inherently worrying about income inequality and free-market fundamentalism. Prompted to support their belief, the recycled and clichéd argument of income inequality being the natural and virtuous outcome to an alignment, a matching up as such, of those with rare skills and ability with commensurate riches is often regurgitated. By this notion, therefore, those able to afford private education are more worthy of the higher salaries they earn in later life when employed. From a different angle, it could equally (and more credibly) be viewed as discriminatory against poorer families, not to mention being inhibitive, rather than conducive, of equal opportunity. 

What is afoot at present are two contemporaneous “gilding ages”. Within the emerging economies – known popularly by the BRIC acronym (though certainly not limited to this group) – the first and arguably most significant one is taking place; here, the pivotal industrial age, as experienced by the UK and United States, is finally and welcomingly apace. Propelled by the dual forces of industrialisation (the transition from agriculture-based activity to manufacturing) and globalisation, it is not seldom for economic growth to be in stratospheric double figures. The economic conditions characteristic of these latent economies are the very reason for their rapid growth. China, India and Brazil are among the World’s five most densely populated countries. It is with these vast populations that both their significantly sized labour markets and unbeatably low wages are explained. The necessary institutions and infrastructure are concretely in place, too. Multinationals, thereby, are attracted en masse into the countries, setting up manufacturing facilities; those who demonstrate a moment of reluctance and hesitancy are often left to wither and die out, as by the time they do decide to relocate it is normally too late. The dynamics of the world economy are so interrelated and fast-moving that hesitancy is a deadly mistake. Even though the fruits of such prosperity are unevenly shared, dissatisfaction among the inhabitants of these countries is paradoxically unlikely. But when the alternative is a reversion to the conditions of a previous era(s), it quickly seems preferable. At least with industrialisation, a demand for labour (and thus their services) is created – not something that resonates with the agriculture, self-subsistence society of pastimes. Indeed, for the legions of middle and working class peoples in the far-away developed nations globalisation, outsourcing, and the growing interdependency between countries is a source of discontentment - what reason does a large multinational have to continue production in the UK when they can readily relocate to, say, India and pay a wage 25 times as less? Then, in simultaneity, another gilded age is in process, predominating in the developed world and is related to technology and its advancement.

Culture

The super-rich are aware their lavish lifestyles do not go unnoticed, out of the public's scrutinous glance. In fact, the extravagance on display is a source of contempt for some. To give something back to society, and disprove the stereotype of all billionaires being greedy megalomaniacs, a large majority are heavily involved or affiliated in one way or another to a philanthropic organisation. Remember the insane wealth of these individuals, so in question is not a couple of meagre million - donations are commonly in the billions, funnelled through an organisation or think-tank often set up under their name and towards a cause they are personally empathetic or sympathetic of. Take the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, for example, responsible for donations of $28 billion as of May 2013. Or George Soro’s Open Society Foundations, involved in important issues such as the foundation’s “Global Drug Reform Policy”. Instead of watching passively, without hope or belief, these deep-pocketed individuals are proponents of positive and active change in policies and ideologies that to them, and resoundingly to others too, are not something to be continued and definitely not something to be strived for. Such is why these charitable deeds deserve and warrant laud.

So, I think the fact there is a small coterie of individuals with more money than is wise has been affirmed. From this point of view, it is difficult to see who benefits from the present state of affairs, apart from the superrich themselves of course. But, as will soon become clear, there are some, and increasingly this some is becoming many. Only recently has this inchoate cohort grown in numbers, at complete servitude to the plutocrats of the world. It is the international, nomadic tradesman – and when I say tradesman, I do not mean plumbers, electricians, and carpenters, but rather lawyers, decorators and property developers and the like who are able to demand a seemingly extortionate sum in the eyes of the ordinary person in exchange for their services. For people such as Rinat Akhmetov, a Ukrainian businessman and oligarch however, the purchase of a $233 million palatial home is a small price to pay when your personal fortune is approximately $12.7 billion. The services these individuals can offer are often unique in nature, not easily imitated which makes any imitations inferior, ersatz. But as inequality goes on widening, more people  are joining the ranks of the multi-billionaires (albeit at an incremental rate) and as a result these idiosyncratic tradesmen (and women) can sit by idly and watch whilst their commissions exponentially rise (no doubt with a wolfish countenance).

Causes

That concludes the historical and cultural timeline of 20th century income inequality, (not by any means comprehensive, though). So, I suppose it’s important to discuss how such an obviously pernicious reallocation of income has become institutionalised? The forthcoming section will be a full-hearted attempt at answering this interesting question. Of course, a definitive answer would require a near infinite amount of time, explaining an almost inexhaustible number of reasons, which is why, and probably to your benefit (if you value your time), I will only identify the salient ones.

The Gilded Age is not an appealing era, not least for its notoriety as a period in which a handful of ‘robber barons’ employed unscrupulous, exploitative means to achieve devastatingly large returns. Why then, are the income and wealth inequalities of today so reminiscent of such a period? In fact, commentators have gone as far to label this new precedent of inequality as the second Gilded Age within Western society. So, if indeed the commentators are correct in their representation, what has caused this so-called second Gilded Age?

On an International Context

Let’s begin with the most obvious ones. Outsourcing, as touched on above, is principal to the widening of incomes. The relocation of manufacturing bases to countries categorised as “developing” or “emerging” are welcomed with open arms (and often preferential treatment; think low tax rates, free land, and export-tax exemptions) by the host country. They create jobs for locals, many of whom are on the brink of, or affected by, privation, and kick-start a virtuous process of cyclical consumption by injecting foreign investment into the economy. In hyper-competitive markets, it makes perfect sense for multinationals to seek out the cheapest labour – sometimes a deciding influence on who remains in business and who is uprooted and replaced. Sympathetic indeed, it is helping those in need of the most assistance; not everyone gains, however - the indigenous of developed countries, particularly among jobs entailing manual labour, tend to be thoughtlessly laid off as a result of outsourcing. On the whole, though, outsourcing does more good than harm. The process has the effect of suppressing the wages of manual labour roles, which is why its role and progression is so important and integral to income inequality.

Unlike in centuries gone by, labour is now more mobile and unconstrained than ever before. Transportation, by whichever myriad method chosen, is cheaper than ever before – and significantly quicker. This is important for today’s globalised labour force, they can now pursue opportunities not only in their home country but in any other country. It is liberating and democratising. In convergence with this trend is a more active participation in education – on finishing school, progression to college, and then university afterwards is now the norm, in contrast to only attending the compulsory school years, to immediately join the labour force thereafter. Together, these two forces – a globalised labour force and greater numbers of educated individuals – are a win-win for businesses (especially multinationals). First, it broadens their selection, and by extension, bargaining power. Second, and it is this the point I intend to accentuate, it suppresses the going wage-rate rather effectually. Today, the past-impossibility of being in competition with an individual of origin to a developing or poor country, Brazil for example, is an all-too-present possibility for a developed, Western country native. As is often the case, both are inseparable academically, holding the same qualifications – the important difference lies in the Brazilian’s willingness to accept a lower salary. This is not only happening on a single person basis either, whole populations of academic institutions are being made redundant. Just note the rapid growth displayed by India’s very own “Silicon Valley” (also known as Bangalore). Lucrative research projects often externally sourced to American Universities are in a motion of decline, and instead companies are now viewing Bangalore as a perfectly sound alternative, for a significantly lower fee. For individuals, there was an ability to contest the salary when the labour pool wasn’t so extensive, but now such deliberation has ceased to be a possibility – there will be someone else willing to accept the stated conditions, at least for the foreseeable future. This variable, in addition to outsourcing, combine to form a very effective relieve mechanism in times of high demand, disallowing the wage rate to rise.

Production – as in actual production, how goods and services are synthesised - is constantly revolutionised, and with each new wave of revolution the capital versus labour debate is frequently reignited and recontextualised to take account of the change in parameters. Ultimately, what every businessman aims for is income (this even goes for non-for-profit organisations, but it is relegated to a secondary objective). Once attained, the much-relieved businessman can do one of two things, broadly speaking: allocate the income between either labour (wages) or capital. In this instance, capital refers to instruments such as dividends, profits, and interest. Increasingly, at least over the past four decades, the amount of income being allocated to capital is incrementing upwards, and is likely to persist into the future. This is problematic, of course; it is a stark representation of income inequality becoming worse (more income going to capital is only compatibly possible if there is a corresponding and proportionate fall in the amount going to labour). In the past, rents on land was the predominant form of capital; today, thanks in large part to the rapidity in computerisation, it can be found in numerable manifestations. The growing presence of capital (in that it now takes numerous different forms) is partly to blame for this uneven capital/income share; but the onus is unambiguously upon technological change. Technology, naturally, is very effective at attaining a higher productivity; this is relishing news for producers. For employees it often precedes redundancies. For someone in employment, the possibility of another person taking their job is now a subordinated worry; their main competition, which could quite effortlessly put them out of work, is inanimate automation. 

Causes endemic to developed, Western countries

Amid the Thatcherite period, deindustrialisation spread rampantly across the UK, most notably in the mining towns (or, in other words, the North). Around this time, economic orthodoxy saw an inexplicable potential in the financial services. So nascent, or so they thought, the authorities allowed the manufacturing sector, still in the recovery phase after Thatcher’s vicious beating, to go unassisted. Soon, the manufacturing industry and all its interconnected sectors were marginalised, incarcerated to an aura of inferiority. Ushered in as a “fitting” replacement was a tsunami of financialisation, concentrated almost exclusively in London, and was startlingly prescient of what the future held – it was the initial building block of the soon-to-be domineering financial megastructure. Incidentally, it was this exact megastructure, so seemingly impenetrable and impervious, that collapsed in the 2008 crisis, giving way to a haphazard disarray of rubble, deflated ebullience, and empty pockets. Through her little self-centred bubble, Thatcher wholeheartedly believed an expansion of financialisation at the expense of manufacturing to be a wise and judicious decision. What she either stupidly forgot or purposefully ignored was the critical difference between the two: 
financial services employ vastly fewer people than manufacturing. Unemployment, therefore, was the only outcome. The people safe from the misfortune of unemployment were the chief executive officers (CEOs) at the top of the organisational hierarchy. Instead of being faced with no prospects and dependency on the government, these individuals actually saw substantial increases in their salaries; they were and still are able to demand a salary they view as fit, one reflective and correspondent to their apparently exceptional “marginal productivity”. The bonus culture, too, awards these same CEOs with more millions, in times of either profit or loss. In more recent years, deindustrialisation remains in a less malicious form and has manifested itself in service-based industries. Notorious for their poor satisfaction, these line of works pay poorly too. I hold a reasoned dislike towards statistics (mainly because my past history with Mathematics is, on the whole, unpleasant) – but on an objective level, and in this instance, they are of real value and indisputable persuasion. By carefully tracking data over time, Thomas Piketty, author of the seminal but rather long and dense Capital in the Twenty-First Century (at 696 pages the “rather” is definitely disputable), shows conclusively how the share of national income apportioned to the top centile (that is, the richest 1%) has risen by a significant amount since the 1970s. Indeed the 70s were a time of relative equality; inequality was subdued, neither as rife or problematic as today; in the UK, United States, and Australia the top centile held 6-8% of national income. Leapfrog to the early 2010’s and across all countries this share has increased, in varying degrees however. The United States witnessed the largest hike, from around 8% to nearly 20%. Not quite as significant, the top centile in the UK controlled 14-15%. Meanwhile, in Australia the top centile absorbed a further 2%, bringing the subtotal up to 10% of national income. Besides the predominant English-speaking countries, elsewhere, too, the wealth of top centile became more concentrated. In Europe, for example, the majority of countries saw a further 2-3% deposited into the bank accounts of the top centile, subtotalling between 7-10% dependent on which country. The general pattern, with unfaltering consistency, was a sizeable enrichment of the top centile. In particular, both the United States and the UK are distinguishable by their high double figure percentages. Another particularity of these two countries is an important common feature: they both pursued a strategy of financialisation. It is very easy to mistake causation; but given how the other countries, in Europe and indeed across the globe (even Japan), were not too enthusiastic to build a significant reliance on financial services, insofar as the funds generated by the sector were multiple times the revenue from the entire manufacturing industry, a condition both the case in the UK and United States satisfied, it illustrates a positive and direct relationship between financialisation and income inequality. For the sake of perspective, I will strive to explain to the best of my ability just how extreme income inequality has come, using the United States as a factual example. The top centile, as stated above, controls roughly 20% of national income. With the help of microscopic analysis, I will go even more specific and examine the top 0.1%. Given the top 1% own 20% of national income, this corresponds to a salary two-hundred times the national average for the top 0.01% (for example, if the average is $30,000 then the salary of each individual within this small cohort will take home $6 million per annum).

What can be identified as another cause of the income disparity, and contributing to its pronouncement, is the hollowing out of employment opportunities that lie at the midpoint of the wage-rate/salary spectrum. Entering the job market can be an exciting task: today, however, it is tarnished more by mundanity than excitement; those seeking employment are limited in their choice to, increasingly, either low or high paid work – which one depends largely on whether one has the prerequisite qualifications and experience. In essence, then, prospective employees without these preconditions will be confined to the monotony of uninteresting work and a hardly sufficient payslip. A noticeable lack of opportunity for progression to more advanced and well paid roles, ensures the income gap remains intact, even widening. All that remains is a huge vacuous gap separating the rich and the poor; the middle-class has been marginalised to such an extent to endanger the populations very existence. In an attempt to assuage the restlessness of the working class population, reports and publications alike have lionised and emphasised the materialisation of a new middle class, which they are the constituents of.  The old working class has moved into the "vacuous space" between the rich and poor; they are now the new middle class. There is of course a new working class to replace the old constituents. Indeed, the very reason such a claim can be purported, is since the hollowing out of the previous middle class has been done so decisively, the working class - when financial income is unaccounted for - have moved up the class system. When income is incorporated into the picture, it’s a completely different story. Now the extent of the disparity becomes all too clear – though they constitute a new class, at least according to government reports, their incomes are not reflective of this progression; in fact, incomes, for the large part, are stubborn with very little differentiation and for some, income has actually fallen. At best, what is prevalent is an upsurge in the petite bourgeoisie.

One would expect the employee to be held in the highest regard and to be of greatest value to all organisations. After all, without human labour, organisations of any kind would quickly turn dysfunctional. (Labour is substitutable with machinery; but like all things, machinery is fallible and, inevitably, at some point will breakdown requiring human intervention). Why then, are employers so persistent in scaling back the expenditure spent on wages whilst, simultaneously, augmenting the salaries of executives? In transit already, those most severely affected by this most undeserving of pay cuts (wages may not have fallen in absolute terms – that is, from £8 to £6 an hour – but when inflation is took into account, purchasing power has fallen) are turning to other sources of income, mainly debt and credit. Debt dependency is anathema; it provides an instance of momentary respite for those affected by financial difficulty, only to place them in an even more dire state. Debt implicates regular interest repayments, adding further stress and helplessness upon the borrower. Instead of placating their financial troubles, it serves as an exacerbation mechanism. That debt is increasingly being viewed as a viable recourse, to escape financial difficulty, ought to evoke at least bit of a sympathy from the government. That it does not, at least to the degree  one would hope for, is worrying. The poor in particular and the middle class to a lesser extent suffice on a relatively lower income in contrast to their rich counterparts. For this very reason, both groups tend to spend a greater proportion of their income - in economics jargon, this is known as a high marginal propensity to consume. This is to be expected, of course. For a worker on the minimum wage, food, shelter, and a plethora of other associated costs will exhaust a majority share of their income. This situational scenario will be different for a millionaire; they will almost definitely have income to spare (unless profligacy is a practised pastime). It is with this leftover income that speculations and general stock market activities are financed. Similar to the marginal propensity to consume, the one of most relevance to the rich is the marginal propensity to invest; that is, what proportion of their income is used to pursue investment opportunities. Together, the two make for a precarious concoction. Income inequality is not assistful in addressing the problem; in fact, it actually exacerbates the tumultuous nature of both processes. Debt and (assumptively profitable) investment are self-sustaining activities, in the sense that, by procuring debt, at some future point, there is likelihood that more will be procured, and so on. While investment, (if consistent), delivers continued returns to the investor, debt creates a figurative stranglehold upon the borrower.

A broad consensus among the medley crew of conservatives and neoliberals is an unanimous agreement on the frequently posed statement that public debt is a real and growing problem. That being said, it is improbable to disappear at any point soon, and should therefore be accepted (begrudgingly for some) as it is. After all, as long as the government can be meet the obligatory interest payments, everyone is contented (at least for now; a government in the future will undoubtedly be bitter about the decision). To argue that this state of affairs has no concerning or alarming aspects would implicate the commentator guilty of superficiality. It would be easy to make such a false judgement, however – but none the less it would be wrong. In short, the problem lies with who is financing the mounting levels of government debt. And it is a significant problem. By buying large numbers of governments bond, and forfeiting the aspect of access and immediacy to the money, the individuals and institutions responsible are guaranteed a modest return. They receive a stable flow of interest and after the predetermined time period the principal sum is reimbursed. Pension funds, banks, and other institutions who are entrusted with large sums of money purchase governments bonds. The mega rich, too, are enticed by the negation of volatility. In effect, the government is dependent on the generosity of the rich. The realisation of the rich’s ulterior motive, a stable and reliable source of income, dilutes this generosity into greed. They just want a safe bet and one in which more money can be made as a result of. In sum, as public debt enlarges (as it has done in consecutive years), the payments being made to the rich and their friends, in the form of interest and bond maturity payouts, proportionately enlarges too. The rich are the only beneficiaries here. And the rich alone. Me and you (unless your a millionaire) will see an implicative effect upon public services, a reflection of the eroded budget presented to the government.

Given the extremity of income inequality in today’s age, one might rationally expect some kind of collective revolt, some kind of stand against the inequities as a demonstrative response. In the not-too-distant future, perhaps, such an expectation may well materialise and become reality. Nevertheless, the evidential damage of income inequality is around for all to bear witness to (the following section, “Implications”, will divulge some of the nasty side-effects). In spite of these unpalatable blemishes, action, with the exception of the Occupy movement, has been virtually non-existent. This widespread passivity is indeed bizarre, and worth taking a moment to explain. Ultimately, at the very centre of this paradox is the role of societal norms. There are norms entrenched in all societies; what they valorise is contingent upon a country’s economic, political, and ideological stances. Both the UK and the United States share numerous features, indeed one is how societal norms are similar. The free-market is embraced more enthusiastically, individualism is an extolled virtue, and the extent of class division is more pronounced than elsewhere. How people perceive finance and the millionaire and billionaire culture is almost the same with negligible difference. Indeed there is a marked laxity towards the excessive bonus culture and 7-digit salaries. Such a perception has not been moulded over night; perpetual protestations of the virtues of finance and intellectually unsound arguments in favour of income inequality have no doubt been instrumentally helpful. The media, too, is instrumental in the construction of such a perception. The industry is dominated by the same influential individuals who are part of the same close-knitted and mutually beneficial community as the financiers and politicians. Available to society is a choice of two outlooks: the first is a radical change of societal norms; the second is to remain passive until income inequality reaches a point of intolerability (as it inevitably will) - even for those who are staunch believers of the norms that assert otherwise.

Implications

Deindustrialisation has paved the way for a service based economy, one that has relinquished the supposed virtues of Fordism (that is, a mode of production that emphasises mass standardisation) in exchange for its more mature variation, Post-Fordism (that is, a mode a production that emphasises small-batched differentiation, with a large degree of flexibility). It is a rise of the precariat, with a simultaneous fall of the traditional proletariat.  As part of this change, employers are stipulating a more pliable and expendable workforce. Job security has fallen to a new low; full-time positions are dwindling in number. What remains for those seeking employment are roles of a flexible, part-time nature. The employer has the power to enforce involuntary redundancies with very little notice. Those on the receiving end of this complete powerlessness are majoritively poor, working class citizens; individuals in capricious circumstances. For the demand of their labour to be decided by the whims of the market is particularly unfair given how their livelihood is contingent on the proposed wage.

This ongoing divergence between the rich and poor ceased to be something that can be selfishly ignored and swept under the carpet, so to speak, a long time ago. With inflation persisting, though at a modest rate, the middle and working class are being placed at a greater disadvantage by the imperceptible effect of wage erosion. As the income gap is left unaddressed, the cost of living – the ability to afford inalienable necessities such as simple sustenance and shelter - is exhausting an increasingly higher amount. Inevitably, as the cost of living rises, people become more financially strapped, slipping towards the poverty line. Already, this pernicious yet avoidable process is being experienced by some members of society. To them, complete or partial dependency on governmental support programs is viewed as the only possible recourse. Without the benevolent state, and the payouts and other supportive measures it provides, there is no possibility of reassurance for those at greatest vulnerability. To discard visceral tendencies and be critical about this chosen response to impoverishment will uncover the hardly subtle fact that, although payouts may indeed be effectual, their efficiency and more importantly sustainability are both questionable. With a ballooning budget deficit a principal problem in most Western countries, a lenient stance towards inequality of income and complete indifference towards its perpetuation is an awful folly; government payouts will only account for a growing proportion of the budget, exerting more pressure upon other public services – the police, health service, and emergency services – which, because of neglection, will likely deteriorate in quality.

The once preeminent competitive position of the UK is now and has been in a state of crumbling decline over the past three decades, due in large part to a deteriorating productivity. At best, this may seem remotely related to income inequality; on closer inspection, there is a clear case of interdependency between the two. How this state of affairs has come about is largely due to a changing perception of finance. Just watch the 10 o’clock news and undoubtedly presented in front of you will be more evidence of the glorification of the stock market. Spurious claims about the stock market have only further increased the sector’s popularity. But this growing dependency on financialisation is not as wholesome as it might come across. Rather than benefiting the economy through the creation of new capital, there is an ongoing movement of existing capital – of both a financial and human kind – to financial services at the expense of manufacturing. Now as a large part of research and development is conducted in manufacturing, a crippling corollary is that the industry has been subject to a worrying depletion in funding, and the number of innovations engineered will be lower. Rather than useful, novel inventions that will be of assistance to the ubiquitous person in ordinary life, the innovations coming to fruition are ones related to finance; these are exclusionary by nature and are of use to the small minority (whom, incidentally, are financially secure) that engage in stock market activities. In large part accountable for the 2008 economic crisis, the Collateralised Debt Obligations (CDOs), essentially a complex derivative of mortgages, shows quintessentially what type of innovation we can anticipate in the future. Even more recently, financial institutions have become increasingly dependent on what to the common layman would appear as a bunch of random letters and numbers thrown together, but what are properly known as algorithms. With these complex formulaes, the trade of financial instruments has been computerised, and, as a result, significantly expedited. High frequency trading, to assign a name to the process, is the latest practice in contention, and rightly so, as it disadvantages the likes of pension funds and ordinary investors, not to mention being the causation of unnecessary volatility. Today, businesses are viewed as expendable entities, only useful for their instrumentality to profit. Nobody is concerned or impelled to care about the vitality of manufacturing; in fact, ever since the indelible Thatcherism period, the industry has been victim to unceasing antagonism, evidenced by the downplaying of unionisation. The World Economic forum, a non-profit organisation, carried out a systematic survey into the competitiveness of those nations that viability allowed, and what it found was that the UK, having been at respectable 7th place, was demoted to 13th in 2009, respectively. The relationship between income inequality and the UK’s competitiveness is inextricable – as more funds are absorbed by the ever-proliferating pool of equities, derivatives, and the constancy of other financial-innovations, investment into the industries with the greatest scope for job creation is inexcusably negligent. Entrepreneurialism, too, is expanding at a negligible rate, evoking a sense of pity for those with a genuine zeal for creativity and audacity. Financialisation, in its culmination, is now so ubiquitous that, increasingly, it is coming to be the only career path for graduates of a business related discipline. This in itself is a waste of talent and potential, given the trivial nature of the expected tasks, very few of which are productive of societal well-being.

Warning: the next point may come across as a far-fetched impossibility. Income inequality has innumerable characteristics; for the following point, the one of relevance is its inherent apocalyptic nature. That is, when it reaches a certain point, one not too distanced from today's, public goods (those that are essential for society to function, go undersupplied in a purely market economy, and which only the government is able to provide), will curtail in supply by such an amount as to warrant the labelling of insufficiency, and what little is supplied will not be of a sound quality. Just envisage such a scenario: while the rich live happily and hold a disproportionate share of national income, a contagion is infecting more and more swathes of people, the primary symptom of which is a manifestation of poverty and immiseration. There will be no need to imagine this far from rosy picture, in fact, as at some eventual moment in time it will become reality – unless the problem of income inequality is decisively addressed. Secluded in this privileged way of life, away from the prying eyes of the public, the rich will have no reason to demand governmental services; vital amenities the ordinary person is thankful for – the police, healthcare service, and educational centres – will go underutilised. Of course, the rich of all people need to feel secure and safe, and increasingly so, fostering a demand for a privatised, but not necessarily more efficient, version of these publicly funded amenities. Just take note of the burgeoning markets of private security, private doctors and schools and the like. The primary (and probably only) consumer group for this emergent market being, of course, the rich and superrich.  With no reason to use public services and less empathy shown towards their poorer counterparts, the rich, as plainly selfish and greedy as it is, will attempt to circumvent tax impositions to a larger extent than guilty of today. So concerned with avoiding taxation the government will be implicated with a shrinking budget to finance important public services. That noted, the crucial investments into innovation, which have included advances in biotechnology and perhaps the 20th century’s most pivotal phenomenon, the internet, will not receive the much-needed funding required. Underinvestment is a ruinous ailment, not only for the present day’s populace but for future generations, too. Places of education, in particular, are especially affected by this eventuality; underinvestment in, say, a public school will have an implication on the quality of teaching. There is an inextricable link between this underinvestment, which will only exacerbate to an intolerable level, and the dilution of the wondrous notion of equality of opportunity. Becoming properly educated is one of a very few means a child from a disadvantaged background can use to guarantee his or her place at a reputable organisation; so if education does succumb to this far from conclusive end, then as a corollary, so will equality of opportunity. It is easy to dismiss this scenario of course; surely a unified response by the governments of the world will intervene and redistribute income more fairly by means of more progressive tax rates, for example? But equally as so, why has intervention not been forthcoming to such an extent to date? Why, then, will the governments of the world decide to intervene at such a late date; surely the rich minority at this point will have even more power and influence? How does the increasingly powerless and feeble government enforce these redistributive policies? Sadly, if anything the government will be acquiesced and become a loyal servant to the elite minority. 

On an intergenerational perspective – that is, over several generations - rich families tend to remain rich; one explanatory argument is how their children tend to excel in education, outperforming poorer counterparts; this consolidates the guarantee of a luxurious upbringing for their offspring, and so forth. This particularly unfair aspect of income inequality is not necessarily overlooked, but rather, being so ingrained in society to the extent that it has been normalised, it is taken at face-value, for granted as such, and people feel no reason to question whether it is fair or not. Societal positions are neither immutable, nor easily malleable – it requires significant and sustained effort, skill, and also luck and good fortune to progress from a lower hierarchical echelon to one considerably higher. Technically speaking, this inequity stems from an inverse relationship between income inequality and social mobility. In other words, as the income gap widens, the offspring of relatively poor and remotely well-off families will find it increasingly challenging to progress up the hierarchical structure of society. Money is the means to most ends; and, as such, education is one. Rich families can afford to enrol their children into a life of exclusivity, beginning at private schools. The juxtaposition in educational opportunity is stark: on the one hand, the poor, often concentrated in the same neighbourhoods, have no choice in where to send their children, limited to an ordinary public school – disruptive pupils are more likely, overcrowding is more likely, poor teaching is more likely; then, on the other hand, the rich are able to choose from a preponderance of private schools. Surprise surprise, it is in the United States that this problem, like several others discussed, is most pronounced; only 9 percent of students enrolled at the most selective and prestigious colleges come from the bottom half of the population (in terms of income), while an overwhelming 74 percent are from the top quarter – for a country that endorses “equality of opportunity”, such a statistic convincingly argues otherwise. A long time before school comes into the parent’s contemplative thoughts, when their offspring is just a baby, devastation by either reduced income or even forced redundancy (an increasingly commonplace scenario), often means not only the sacrifice of sustained and frequent one-to-one socialisation with the baby (a reduced wage necessitates longer working hours), but perhaps even more important, there is a likelihood that the baby will be brought into a family more prone to interfamilial problems, whether that be domestic violence, substance abuse, or just neglect of the baby. Unfortunately, this is a real and widespread problem. Equality of opportunity is made even more untenable by the fact that rich families are able to cover the associated costs of an unpaid internship, a benefit poor families cannot afford. A pretty stark and illuminating statistic is that the average income of Harvard University student’s parents is $450,000, placing them comfortably in the top 2% income strata. With social mobility in a downward descent, the problem of income inequality is made even more difficult to tackle, and in time, overcome.

For those unsympathetic towards economics, I apologise in advance as the following point is comprised of its fair share. Conservative thinkers will be flabbergasted to be informed that a wage above the going market rate is, in fact, desirable (yes, that means going against the wisdom of the market!). Hypothesised by Alfred Marshall, the efficient wage theory, for its actual name, puts forth an interesting premise: namely, by guaranteeing employees a wage or salary greater than what the market asserts (the sheer sacrilege!), their productivity will be higher. For Neoliberals and Conservatives alike this will no doubt be viewed as heresy to Economics. As discussed above, the dual forces of automation and outsourcing are both responsible for the hollowing out jobs, especially ones providing a wage above the nation’s average; for the poor, and increasingly the middle class, the remaining opportunities consist of poorly paid, dissatisfying jobs - jobs being taken on for the financial reward and nothing else. On this typically low wage employees have no reason to work painstakingly and, thus, by decree of Marshall’s theory, productivity is unlikely to rise anytime soon (unless of course there is a technological breakthrough; but then again, this may result in redundancy). Importantly, this is merely hypothetical and is not empirically and positivistically proven. Yet it does present an interesting idea that is intuitively plausible.

I hate to bring further attention to the Great Recession, the ripples of which are still with us today. But for the next point such invocation is necessary. Unresolved even now, almost 6 years after the downturn “officially” ended, what caused the sudden calamity remains in deliberation. On the limitless discussion board, a handful of partisans each with loyalty vouched to a different doctrine assert equally as disparate analyses. Although some have argued against it, and in vain I may add, the finance sector is to be held with a large degree of culpability. To answer why is not in the scope of this blog; what is, however, is a closer examination of the responsive policy chosen by those in power. Already encumbered by huge fiscal deficits, fiscal policy was vociferously dismissed; instead, and most ruefully, a scaling back of public expenditures and welfare services was opted for. To recap, then: firstly the bankers and financiers were kindly bailed out to the tune of £123.93 billion in the UK alone, and then secondly, completely undeservingly, they receive more preferential treatment -  in a different form this time: rather than being subject to more progressive tax rates, the government settled for a policy known for its eviscerating tendencies, Austerity. What can be said about this perverse choice of action is how the government, and more specifically, the empowered officials, fell victim to naïvity, believing unquestioningly the rhetoric and proclamations voiced by the financiers and bankers. They curated the alarmingly idealistic image of finance as a virtuous process, to which the government and regulators ingenuously believed. It is a classic and exemplar case of regulatory capture; an instance whereby the regulator has unwittingly internalised the objectives and morals of the party under regulatory supervision. The interests of the finance sector are thereby prioritised over the common taxpayer – paradoxical, given how the mandate of regulation is to do otherwise.


The redistribution (or, rather, maldistribution) of income in effect today is both obvious and subtle in its consequences. It is important to take account of both, given how subtly can often be more harmful than conspicuity. A new (and hopefully profitable) investment is a cherished opportunity for the rich. As the migration of income carries on travelling from the poor to the rich, new investments can be pursued; more important, around the feet of the rich now exists a more spacious and greater financial cushioning to fall back upon if an investment turns sour. For this reason, the chosen investments are of an increasingly risky nature, reflected commensurately by their higher return. While an unfruitful bet is always a possibility, it does not have the same deterring effect illustrated by the relatively poor because of the huge difference in personal wealth. It is less likely for someone with a below-average income to make investments, however with less disposable income, they become even more risk-averse and show a greater degree of reluctance towards investment and related activities. That part of their income is place at jeopardy is the deciding deterrent - even if there is a potentiality of gaining a significant monetary return. For those with millions or billions, a privileged life can be preserved and financed by simply putting a few million aside for strictly investment purposes - and of course, this is on top of their 7-digit salary. As an activity, investment is exclusionary, only those with a specific personal wealth can turn their inclination into practice; this is an unavoidable aspect of course, but it is one that as a result of, puts a restrictive straitjacket upon who and who cannot engage in these high payoff gambles (as that's what they essentially are).

Inequalities of any kind are, by their very nature, divisive. This rings particularly true for income inequality. Too busy jet-setting around the globe, the plutocratic minority seldom interact with the rich; likewise, the rich seldom interact with the well-off; and the well-off seldom interact with the poor. Pervading around all societies, in varying degrees, is an implicit (and increasingly explicit) class division; that is, a hierarchical arrangement that purposefully assorts each individual a societal status in accordance with a myriad of determinants. Akin to the bizarre sorting hat that appears in the first Harry Potter film, rather than different houses, the process of class division assorts each individual a different social pecking order. Within unequal societies, class division is deeply entrenched. The problem with this obvious case of stratification is how it is inhibitive towards a society promotive of trust; a society in which individuals can walk down a road without trepidation, without the fear of being victimised by some form of physical violence. Alienated amongst those of the same “class”, interaction with a person outside of this class (particularly of a “higher class”) is not actively encouraged or performed, except out of necessity. In isolation from other classes, a gradual erosion of empathy towards one another emerges. A loss of empathy, in turn, leads to a loss of trust. A loss of trust, in turn, leads to society in which cooperativeness and communitarian values are compromised. A loss of cooperativeness, in turn, leads to an apathetic rich; they no longer feel morally obligated to be charitable and philanthropic. In such a dystopian-esque society, people are constantly on edge, worried about being subject to some form of crime (with no empathy towards each other crime is viewed as permissible), and as a consequence, there is a subsequent effect upon stress and, as substantiated by research, longevity. This vicious set of events is just waiting for some form of impetus to knock over the first domino, to which the remaining ones will quickly follow. Income inequality could well be this impetus.

In similar vein, the more unequal a society is, the greater the incidence of mental health problems. In part, the capitalistic system, and its adjunct consumerism, are at blame; the values that both processes perpetuate – narcissism and ostentatious individualism – create a needless awareness of one’s self-consciousness. People are less concerned about absolute improvements; rather, what matters are relative improvements, in other words, ones vis-à-vis other people. To be affected by a feeling of inferiority in the presence of others is likely to, (and research proves it does), ignite common mental health problems: anxiety, depression, and personality disorder, as well as turning to short-lived palliatives, such as alcoholism and/or drugs. Fashion and designer clothes construct and symbolise a particular style, affiliative of a particular subculture or group. Individualism is indeed a praiseworthy notion, and clothes, to take one example, are just a representation of one’s individual identity. The problem lies with the absurdity of this variation of individualism; people who simply cannot afford the “in” clothes are ostracised and alienated. Exclusion from a group for something so trivial as what one is wearing is not the supposed purpose of life; individuals are supposed to interact and be mutually beneficial to one another. The very notion of consumerism is fundamentally flawed, too; why encourage never-ending consumption given the limited, finite number of resources on the planet? Anyway, that is a completely different story. As I was saying before that minor digression; in more unequal societies, the difference in material possessions and outward appearance is wider. Stressfulness is one of the unpleasant side-effects of this poisonous ailment.  Everybody knows that stress can cause long-term harm to the sufferer; what very few people know is how it can change how the stomach functions. As a result, the body for some biologically reason deposits fat around the affected person’s abdomen, rather than their legs. That being said, it is no coincidence that obesity is on the rise. Food is viewed as a route to respite, to escape the anxieties of life – this illustration of “comfort eating” is almost exclusively manifested in the consumption of high cholesterol foods, high sugar content foods, and fast-food. For pregnant women stress is particularly alarming; research has confirmed a relationship between stressed pregnant women and their offspring being brought into a life that presupposes stress. Adapted to deal with stress, their metabolism will be relatively slower, a problem in itself as obesity will be a more likely to be fixture in later life. In more primitive times when the problem of food shortages and paucity were an omnipresent worry, such resilience would be beneficial, even life-saving; in today’s world, however, a world characterised by an abundance of food (in the developed world at least), obesity is a more probable outcome.

In an utopian world of perfect equality, crime would be a long forgotten problem of pastimes. That an overwhelming proportion of criminal offenses are committed by individuals on the fringe of financial sufficiency and insufficiency is not surprising. The more unequal a society is, the more the whole notion of class division is acknowledged and valorised. For those at the bottom of this social hierarchy, they lack the financial means to present themselves in the same materialistic way as those in the higher classes. Even above a specific income threshold in which the necessities of life are affordable, the person is forced to forgo other goods and services, ones of no intrinsic value, no actual utility, but are nonetheless meaningful for other purposes, as an affirmation of a particular style or status, for example. People would not be forced to go to such extremes, to commit such offenses that could rightly brandish them as a criminal and sharply constrain and restrict what opportunities are pursuable in later life or not, if their life was satisfying and fulfilling. In the throes of desperation, crime quickly gains an allure that reconstructs the questionability of the activity. Money dominates almost all facets of life; without money, therefore,  participation in societal life is curtailed. Income inequality is, by definition, the uneven spread of money and can therefore be noted as a direct cause of crime; the more unequal the distribution of money is, the more people will be living on the breadline, so to speak, and will be inclined (out of necessity rather than choice) to engage in activities deemed as illegal and unlawful. The characteristics of a society ravaged by income inequality are, in general, a marked level of individualistic concern, and by extension of this, an unusually tight embrace of consumerism. It constructs an idealised image of what people ought to look. Conformity to this image is a way of attaining acceptance. The individualistic predisposition found in unequal societies, places a significant emphasis on status. Between individuals, status competition is a constantly ensuing anxiety. This point relates closely to research undertook by Harvard Medical School based psychiatrist, James Gilligan. His research found a common motive in the provocation and use of violence to be in response to “the feeling of shame and humiliation – a feeling that is painful, and can even be intolerable and overwhelming – and replace it with its opposite, the feeling of pride”. Thus, for those living on a stagnant income, even falling, the attainment of these idealised “images” are an insurmountable distance away and simply unachievable, and as a direct result, a feeling of shame and humiliation is evoked.


Solutions

The outlook for completely eliminating income inequality once and for all is dim and, to be candid, neither very likely nor desirable. A partial mitigation is a more achievable and less ambitious goal. Such a multifaceted problem is of particular difficulty to address – how does one isolate the myriad of underlying causes and influences? Indeed, in this section I will attempt to do just that.

The first easily identifiable area in which improvement ought to be sought, and one which the manufacturing industry is heavily burdened as a result of, is the scary perversity of incentives inculcated into financiers. There was and still is, albeit to a lesser extent, a misalignment between the motives of the financial sector and societal well-being. What this means, ultimately, is how the ultimate objective or telos of the sector being strived for, is incompatible with societal well-being. This misalignment is infectious, and can be found in an increasing number of industries. Once again, the finance sector reins victorious on how distorted incentives are. Society has been subordinated to personal enrichment. Worryingly, innovation is infected too – why else would the financiers create these super complex financial instruments other than for their own well-being? Their main merit is the diversification of risk, but this is often done by complicating the intricacies of the instruments insofar as making them indecipherable and incomprehensible to regulators. When Warren Buffett, an investor extraordinaire, worth $67.6 billion dollars as of 2014, makes direct reference to derivatives as financial weapons of mass destruction", it is probably worth taking note. In principle (and in accordance with the marginal productivity theory), the wage paid to an employee is supposed to be an exact reflection of societal good derived from the work. In reality, of course, this far from the case, and particularly so for financiers – they contribute very little to society, but extract obscene amounts of money. Given the ultra-competitive nature of finance, newcomers, after securing an exclusive place at whichever hedge fund, equity house, or investment bank it might be, are so determined (to the extent of it being mistook for religiosity zeal) to impress their senior, that the immorality surrounding the conducted practises is simply viewed as acceptable, being openly and unabashedly perpetuated. Regard for the ordinary person or business is implicitly disparaged – all that is of importance is appropriating a sizeable return, by whatever means are necessary and irrespective of any harm caused. The collectives of individuals entrusted with these inordinately large sums of money, are done so with one thing in mind: the expectation of a return. Importantly, it is other people’s money at risk of being lost in this high-stake speculative game; the investor has no emotional attachment towards the ultimate outcome – any money lost due to the vagaries of the market is at loss to someone else. It is this exact indifference that encourages trading reminiscent of the kind preceding the 2008 crisis. By changing this relationship into one in which the financier has something at stake, something to loss, be it their salary or the position itself, a feeling of cautiousness upon their decisions and a direct acknowledgement of the risk entailed in the beyond-audacious investments will be induced. If they have something to loss it will make them think twice – and, as a result, an environment for safer and more secure investments will be created. This is not as easy as it may seem; financiers are expected to make a return - if this return is unforthcoming, therefore, people will view the investor (and also the financial firm they work for) as incompetent and unreliable, and are unlikely to be a repeat customer. That poses the question of how a more cautious environment is to be promoted, one devoid of the significant risk of today, if, by going against the norm and not to pursuing the notably riskier bets, a reasonable return is less likely, and as a result, a simultaneous decline of reputation and custom is more likely?

The large and powerful investment banks publicised for their participatory roles in the 2008 crisis are far too comfortable in their behaviour – they have very little reason to be cautious about which trades are pursued; any unfruitful bets are cushioned and subsumed by the
government, being reimbursed out of the taxpayers’ pocket. To the ordinary economist, this is known as “moral hazard”, an instance whereby one party is assured by another and is therefore able to behave recklessly in the knowledge that if failure or bankruptcy arises recapitalisation will be provided. In this context, party A (the financial institutions) are reassured by party B (the government), and thus in times of crisis party B will intervene and provide recapitalisation. The nature of this problem can be remedied with relative ease. A straightforward solution is to separate the financial institutions into two opposingly different categories: on one hand would be retail banking, under which ordinary banks and the like would fall; banks that handle everyone's personal saving and are a source of credit for individuals – characteristically, these are more risk-averse and have little involvement in the so-called ‘casino banking’; then, on the other hand, investment banking, constituted by the banks and institutions that actively partake in derivative trading and other complex trades. (In fact, these institutions are often referred to as "non-banks"; it appears contradictory at first, but the name makes sense because they have neither a lending nor depositing function - the two defining aspects of a bank). Retail banking will be placed under close surveillance, to ensure adherence to the stringent conditionalities placed upon which banking activities and trades are permitted is abided by. Investment banking, conversely, is fully autonomous and unrestricted in which trades are permitted; with this privilege, however, the bank or institution automatically forfeits the safety net of government intervention, of much convenience in times of crisis. This would be implemented with the intention of promoting a more critical and wary approach to investment, an intention made all the more likely given the withdrawal of the government as a lender of last resort function. It would inject a healthy dose of realism into the matter; as a call on the taxpayer is no longer an option - any money lost is irretrievable, lost for good. Something reminiscent of the discontinued Glass-Steagall act of 1992 would be wise. Complementary to this measure, a removal of the cloak of secrecy encompassing the financial services sector will assist in making the sector more transparent. That such opacity is deemed necessary is reason to speculate about the scrupulosity of the activities; notably risky practises, in turn, will be discouraged.

Overleveraged positions – that is, when liabilities exceed equity/when a company is heavily indebted (for example, the Lehman Brothers had a leverage ratio of 30.7 times during the 2008 crisis) – are characteristic of large financial firms; they are very telling of their activities, too. Taking on board such precariously large sums of money is instrumental and supportive of the hostile takeovers, or “centralisation” in Marxist terms. This is exactly what businessmen have bore witness to and distraughtly experienced over the past decades. The very commonality of these buyouts is indicative of an individualistic culture; if companies are bought, dismantled and sold in quick succession how are they supposed to prosper and grow? What motive is there for research and development funding? It is an abject and sorry state of affairs, and cannot, should not, be casually overlooked. This is all very anticipatory, however; for those scouting out potentially lucrative companies, it is done with only one objective in mind: the maximisation of share value. And it seems rationalisation of the workforce, laying off lots of workers, is the quickest and simplest expedient to realise this objective – even if the inflated share value is short-lived. At the heart of this problem, and where I believe it stems from, is the excessively glorified shareholder culture. What is needed, then, is a suitable replacement in place of this irremediably bad culture; a new paradigm that is emphatic of the common employee, of their needs and expectations, and, equally as important, a dissociation from short-termism. As a complement, the central government and the according department could draw up and ratify a new ownership law. What is special about this particular ownership law is the stipulation of a minimum number of years, in which a new owner or set of owners of a recently taken over company are required to remain in ownership until dissolution is permitted. The financial gain of buying and selling companies in quick succession will cease to be possible, and thus opportunistic financiers will be thwarted in their attempts to do so. Rather, acquisitions and takeovers will become a heralding sign, the beginning of a harmonious relationship between two growth-orientated companies. That is not to say takeovers ought to be banded outright. Because that would be equally as disastrous as allowing them to continue unfettered. Instead, a takeover should only be permitted on receiving a thumbs up from the relevant regulatory power.

It would be naïve to describe the current craze of shareholder dominated companies as a sound organisational structure. Shareholders and heavily compensated seniors will no doubt provide a personal endorsement, but for the remaining employees, the remaining majority, it serves of no benefit. Change is required; specifically a change of organisational
structure. One in mind, and which could revolutionise how companies operate, is an employee-ownership structure, whereby all employees are of equal value. This abstraction of equal value is then transformed into practise by introducing a profit-sharing scheme. No, this is not some dream of a communistic diehard – the owner(s) or CEO(s) will of course receive a salary multiple, ten or perhaps even twenty times that of the workers on the production floor; importantly, though, it will have no resemblance to the excesses of today, where CEOs enjoy salaries one hundred times the average yearly wage. The sense of equality is further reinforced by an allocative share scheme, in which each employee receives a significant number of shares. Indeed, equality is not the only benefit, employees have good reason to work harder in an attempt to increase the share price (a higher share price generally means higher or more frequent dividend payouts). In turn, this concrete linkage between the employee and the company’s very existence gives reason to work vigorously, manifested in a higher productivity. The associative problems of a lack of autonomy and feeling of subordination and inferiority, synonymous with hierarchical and employer-owned/shareholder-owned companies, are quickly forgotten, too. Rather than being coerced into the completion of a task, employee-ownership structures are characteristically democratic. In contrast to hierarchical-structured companies, boardroom meetings are a congregation of actual employees, not representatives of important shareholders; in direct involvement with the company on a daily basis, these employees can provide intricate accounts of how the business is functioning. In Germany, a large proportion of companies embrace a type of capitalism that would be consider deviatory in the US and UK, known as “Rhenish capitalism”. Individualism is replaced by an encompassing concern of the entire workforce; it is frequently referred to as a “stakeholder culture”. To have representatives of workers, regional governments, and environmental groups present at major discussions is a common sight. All these theoretical benefits are all well and good, but, ultimately, what matters is how does the theory stand in practise. Well, to use the example of Mondragon Corporation, a cooperative of Spanish origin, it does mightily well. Beginning as a 120-employee strong company, rapid and sustained growth has allowed the cooperative to expand by such an amount that the current employee count stands at 80,321 and annual sales equate to billions.

Manufacturing, as discussed above, is gripped firmly by an insidious malady, and has been for a worrying number of years. Part of reason to how this condition has developed is firstly, a severe lack of provisioned capital, and secondly, because a large part of available loans are usurious (that is, the proposed interest rate is unsustainably high). This is far from incurable, of course. The government has the means to remedy both problems. A logical solution is the creation of a governmentally-ran institution, whose mandate and purpose would be to appropriate funds to mainly manufacturing companies, at a competitive interest rate and attractive terms. At present, the majority of manufacturers, approximately 85%, lend finance from a measly four lenders. More competition is desperately needed. In the meantime, however, this proposal would stimulate the dormant manufacturing industry into activity again.

An overhaul of the current taxation rates, of which are more than palatable for the rich, is not like some commentators argue without warranty or unreasoned, but is increasingly required by necessity – they are simply too modest and are in need of being hiked upwards. It is presently the poor and middle class who are suffering by implication of the regressive taxation rates (this means the poor pay a greater proportion of their income in tax than the rich); to them taxation is something to be accounted for in their ever-dwindling budget, an unavoidable obligation that is heartfelt; to the rich it is a mere inconvenience. Robert Shiller, an American economist, proposes a novel and interesting tax regime, completely disparate to any before. Built on the premise of linking a change in income to a corresponding but proportionate change in tax, the proposal would predictably sever and mitigate inequalities. Importantly, everyone would be subject to it, and thus the argument, or ad hominem rather, frequently touted by the super-rich expressing concern over their cohort being unduly discriminated against will be void of substance. The fallacious proposition recycled by those on the Right, arguing that the rich need to receive impunity from more progressive taxes, so to preserve the sanctity of incentives is not even worth repudiation. Research by the trio Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Stefanie Stantcheva, found current tax rates to be far from excessive, and are, if anything, extremely modest, even benign. What they found, interestingly, was a percentage of 70% to be an optimal tax rate (that is, the one that would generate the most tax revenue). Of course, on first impressions 70% may appear unfair upon the millionaires (the irony). Then again, the only reason income tax is currently so low in comparison to period after World War 2, is because the efforts of past governments, led by Right Wing and Big Business sympathisers, many of whom had vested interest in lower taxes, spouted a bunch of rhetoric about how laissez-faire capitalism (or Neoliberalism, as it’s known today) was the most advisable economic system.

Surrounding the whole idea of tax havens is an impermeable mystique. For those aware of tax havens, it is common knowledge only a small melange of people and companies successfully seek benefit from their existence. For the remaining 99%, a large majority of whom are not even consciously aware of these centres of secrecy and clandestineness, never mind their discreditable activities, they are detrimental. This is despite the fact tax havens are essentially insatiable black holes with a particular liking for major Western government’s tasty tax revenues. It is disconcerting to know tax havens are ignored by these same governments. In times of strict and painful Austerity measures, surely the
“miraculous” disappearance of billions of taxable income should be a priority? If prompted, intergovernmental action could indeed outlaw such activity and demand more transparency, insofar as making tax havens undesirable. Two parties are guilty of wrongdoing; firstly the superrich, and secondly, the country in which the tax haven is located. Of course, neither would vouch support towards policy that could potentially undermine their prospering relationship and result in a disassembly of the activity, given the inevitable loss of income. Regardless, the affected major governments need to come together and enact a concerted unified response. If unsuccessful in achieving its end (the abolition of tax havens), a last resort and expedient as such is a temporary protectionist strategy. This does not mean something so extreme and punitive as a complete embargo of trade, but rather a partial tariff of say 20 or 30%. In doing so, it will send a strong message to the select number of governments playing host to tax havens. The message would be a complete intolerance towards tax havens. At the centre of balance of payments (BOPs) theory, is the assertion that it is impossible for the countries of the world, in aggregate, to be in either surplus or deficit (that is, a state whereby outflows exceed inflows, and vice versa). In general, developed countries tend to be in deficit, while developing and mainly emerging countries do not, instead running surpluses. Overall, the deficits are cancelled out by the surpluses, at least in theory. This is the problem, however: the current world position defies and contradicts this central theoretical belief: developing and emerging countries do not run balance of payments accounts that are correspondingly diametrical to their developed counterparts (that is, if the developed country is in deficit of £2 million, the developing country is in surplus of £2 million; therefore cancelling to £0). There is a major imbalance; the world’s balance of payments account is in fact negative – in other words, money has quite literally disappeared (or so it seems). Of course, the accounting of the world’s balances of payments is not a straightforward feat; mistakes are almost inevitable, and indeed this explains at least part of the discrepancy – but not all. Recent research by Gabriel Zucman, a London School of Economics (LSE) professor, has made a substantial contribution in understanding this perplexing matter. With his main finding, the mystery of the imbalance is solved. It is because of massive off-the-book movements of finance to off-shore bank accounts and tax havens. In short, this imbalance is unaccounted for money. Worryingly, the amount in question is not a tuppence either, but rather, at a conservative estimate, about 10% of global GDP.

Among the working class pervades an indifference towards anything politicised. They have been effectively depoliticised. For something so important and powerful as politics to be utterly unengaging, especially to such a mass of people, is disturbing. Within this disenfranchisement, however, lies potentiality; if summoned and effectively mobilised, these swathes of people who feel a modicum of empathy at most towards their political masters can come together in unity and make a point too noticeable to be ignored. Other more hesitant folk, too, will be galvanised and prompted into participating in the show of resistance, not only in the country in which the demonstration is occurring but also abroad, in countries afar. Indeed, it would be foolish for people to become disillusioned by what can be achieved with demonstrative action. At the very least, though, the emotive nature of the subject will be captured and transformed into media publications to bring awareness to the problem (not the mainstream ones of course, that would be wishful thinking, but the multiplicity of smaller outlets popping up all the time). Such drastic action is at a breaking point; soon it will performed by necessity, and once materialised it could be unprecedented in numbers and passion. As the inequalities so protrusive in society continue to worsen unabatedly, more people will begin to suffer silently until a revolutionary approach is viewed as the only alternative left.

Exploitation, as anyone whose read Marx will know, is one of many unavoidable ills of capitalism; not just in respect to humans, but also the environment. Companies are accumulating massive riches by happily and unashamedly polluting the atmosphere, by causing irrevocable harm upon the environment. It is a very profitable business, mainly because the environmental damage is not monetised and charged upon the business. These unaccounted for externalities (as they are known in Economics) are of massive benefit to the company; they allow these companies to continue their reckless consumption of the Earth’s resources at very little cost. For inhabitants in close proximity to the source of pollution, the activity is often to their detriment, affecting negatively both their lifestyle and longevity (think about air pollution, for example). One alarming example is deforestation. The rate at which the process is expanding is the very definition of unsustainable. Not to go all science-ey, but this has obvious implications upon climate change and global warming, quickening both processes; it also, and this is more harmful for the immediate future, leads to the permanent relocation of parochial tribes and the complete and unnecessary callous extinction of endangered wildlife. For the sake of perspective, a statistic I have found on the http://wwf.panda.org/ website estimates the effect of deforestation to be accountable for the displacement of 12-15 million hectares of forest every year - or the equivalent of 36 football fields per minute. There is good news, however. These externalities can be accounted for through a process of internalisation. Put simply, what this means is that the externality is internalised and the real cost of the activity, that is, the private cost (e.g. hiring labour) and the environmental cost, are incorporated together and accordingly charged upon the company. Additionally, a heavier tax imposition upon the companies at fault for this environmental degradation is required. Ecologism is in a state of neglect and corruption. But by duly extracting a more equitable sum of these companies, a sum that is a more appropriate reflection of the real (rather than superficial) cost behind their activities, the revenues can be reinvested into the community, into new projects to create employment.



Despite the intrinsic value of education, it remains a vastly underappreciated and, to a certain degree, underutilised service. The present educational curriculum is not necessarily poor as such, but rather, some components are in need of a tweak to ensure the benefit captured from the service is maximised. Given the important implication of education, this ought to be a priority for all governments. A sound education allows students to acquire essential skills, the very skills that differentiate him or her from homogeneity. To properly highlight this point, I will call upon the marginal productivity theory, as previously discussed. In general, the wage of an employee is an approximate reflection of their productivity and “contribution” to the company. One route to a higher productivity is specialised knowledge; or, in other words, becoming educated. This is why a relatively poor education, especially in the current job climate, is inherently stifling; it makes procurement of such intangibles as specialised knowledge more difficult to secure and assimilate. That is not to suggest a complete overhaul of the education system is an obvious panacea. Partly this is the answer, and reshuffling the education system is indeed required; but equally, if not more, as important, is a continual readjustment to the curriculum and material being taught. We live in a world predominated by technology – and it is very welcoming for a number of reasons. But it also has a more sinister side: with the constant progression and innovation that it spurs, skills and knowledge procured from education are entering obsolescence at a faster rate than ever before. On entering the job market, a large part of the material learnt in education quickly loses meaningfulness; the application of such knowledge ceases to be in demand. This underlines the importance of updating the core syllabuses on a yearly basis, and it cannot be understated; if ignorance prevails, and only a significant but one-off change is made, people will benefit from an initial demand for their skills and knowledge. Then, as technology advances and this line of expertise is no longer demanded, it will be condemned to the graveyard of “skills and knowledge of days gone by”, along with the high wage.

In the UK and among an unhealthy number of European nations, the austerity experiment has been nothing short of counterproductive. In some cases, the economic slump it was supposed to amend has actually been deepened. As a direct result of austerity, public services are in a state of chronic underinvestment. The central intention of the policy, reducing the government debt, is indisputably sound. Yet this very debt remains, practically undiminished. Debt per se is not the only problem either, there are the concomitant periodic interest repayments to worry about too. (Given austerity’s contractionary immanence, this should not come as a surprise to anyone). As of 2013, the financial burden upon the UK taxpayer of only servicing the debt (that is, paying the interest repayments) was a not-so-small sum of £45.1 billion. For the sake of perspective, this sum is the equivalent to 6% of total governmental expenditure. Do not let this small percentage detract from the substantiality of the amount. Each pound is being spent on a cause of no avail to the UK taxpayer and general population at large. We find ourselves in a state of regression, retrograde; the economic fruits painstakingly amassed over several years were destroyed in a matter of months during the 2008 economic crisis. The economy, as a result, relapsed into a less developed state. That being said, it is therefore excruciating to have no choice but to sit by passively while such wastefulness is in plain sight. To see such a grotesque amount of the money being whittled away on a purpose of no utility to the ordinary person can and should be stopped; there is a necessity for it to be utilised in a more efficient, more productive way. The need for intervention has turned into desperation. However, like always, there is no utopian solution, and all the courses of action available are, to one degree or another, contentious. And this is particular true for what I believe to be the most well adapted action to tackling the problem - a tax upon wealth. It will be predictably despised and resisted by the small minority who fit the criterion on whether or not they are affected by the policy. Importantly though, the arguments in favour of the policy outweigh the arguments against it by a significant and clear margin. Firstly, it will generate a sum sufficiently large to cancel out and eradicate government debt in its entirety. Secondly, too, the deep structural wealth inequalities within society will be disrupted and upset. A specific threshold will be set, at which level an individual will be levied with the tax if their personal wealth is equal to or above it. If the total value of wealth is significantly above the threshold, a correspondingly higher rate of tax will be levied. Wealth and income are categorically different and not interchangeable concepts. Dividends, rent, and interest each constitute a form of wealth. In general, wealth provides a source of income, often one that the holder of wealth has no contribution in generating; but as the purchaser and owner of the wealth, (a thousand shares, for example), they have an entitlement to a constant flow of income, (a thousand dividends in the e.g.). For wealthy individuals, the stock market and financial meccas of the world have opened up a new avenue in which further fortunes can be amassed. Simply by choosing successful companies, they are guaranteed high yielding returns, returns in the region of 10%. Risk is the main determinant on what return one receives from an investment. The more risky an investment is, the greater the return. Thus, the average return can potentially be substantially higher than 10% depending on how much underlying risk there is across the portfolios. When the amount in question is multiple millions, the subsequent return is significant. In the initial periods after implementation, the tax percentages would be small - nothing exceeding 2% for the wealthiest individuals down to 0.5% for the less, but by definition, still very wealthy. As of April the 8th, Bill Gate's personal wealth totaled $79 billion, up by $16 billion since 2012. Other wealthy individuals, too, are having their personal wealth rise at such a rate. The proposed tax regime, then, would not be too confiscatory; it would implicate a modest amount relative to absolute totals. It would be a recurrent tax, being carried out on a yearly basis. This would provide these individuals with more than enough time to accumulate the amount forgone as a result of the tax. Another important aspect is experimentation. If these individuals are cosily living off their capital gains (be it rents, dividends, or interest), and their overall wealth, in most cases, is not diminishing, the government should not be dissuaded in enforcing a higher tax rate. Progressively, government debt will at some eventual point be entirely nulled. At which point, taxation revenues and other forms of government income will no longer be preordained for debt services - instead, the money will be available to spend on more productive uses such as the debilitated public services.

The last solution, and one that can be deployed in the foreseeable future, is through the medium of politics. That is to say, through political participation, through suffrage, and more generally, through democracy. To correct these deep imbalances, people need to become politicised, their current apathy needs to broken and galvanised into interest and discernment of what politics can achieve. This means, in other words, espousing left-leaning parties, ones that emphasise the virtues of equality, collectivism, and sustainability. In the UK, until recently, this would have been met by an impasse, a hopeless situation with no routes to the planned destination (that is, a left-leaning party). But this has changed, with the meteoric rise of the Green Party, a party that, for the first time in my (admittedly relatively short) life of twenty-one years, I have become a fully pledged member to. I encourage others to, first, read the party's manifesto and, second, evaluatively decide whether the policies resonate with you. If they do, then spare a small sum and - become a member, and the fruits of the decision - more equality, environmentalism, a curtailed and more accountable financial sector, recognition of the rich's moral obligation to contribute more to the government kitty, inter alia - will be immeasurable.

Conclusion

If you have made it to this point in the blog, I commend your perseverance as admittedly, at parts, it can become tedious. But from the majority of the writing I hope you have gathered a more informed picture of why income inequality matters and how it directly infringes on your life and liberty. Equally so, I hope you have realised the growing urgency, necessity in fact, for some form of action, directly and indirectly, to tackle the systemic causes of the process. There is no easy way to go about this, however. For each of the proposed solutions there is often a corresponding shortcoming – some of which make the policy counterproductive and void. Globalisation is largely at blame. The globalised element within finance allows companies and individuals alike to move their personal finances readily from one bank to another, out of one jurisdictional area into another. Of course, as is the case with tax havens and off-shore bank accounts, once the finance has been moved it is out of the government’s tantalizing reach. Nationally, a country is at complete impotence, unable to appropriate income rightfully belonging to the government; globally, as in between a whole host of different countries, and the likelihood of retrieving the income is heightened. More cooperation, therefore, will be beneficial to all involved. All countries are suffering, to one degree or another, from the same woes of income inequality. That a cooperative, unified approach has not been more forthcoming is surprising. The sooner cooperation is collectively agreed upon, the sooner the proposed solutions can be implemented without worry of circumvention.

Qualitatively, a society marked by income inequality characteristically has a greater incidence of mental health problems, obesity, alcohol and/or drug dependency, and crime. Class division (or segregation) and inequality of opportunity are both more pronounced, too. Quantitatively, wages are suppressed among low-income earners (these jobs, too, often provide low job satisfaction), more people are taking on debt as a means to affording basic necessities, and financial governmental assistance is a more commonplace. In general, income inequality is prerequisite to a lower standard of living. To put into perspective how detrimental income inequality can be upon society, the United States spends six times as much on the penal system and prisons than education. At what point does the government want to rid itself of stubbornness and concede to having a deep structural problem? 

In countries in which income inequality is acute, there is an overemphasis upon money. Money is viewed as some transcendental object; the ultimate means. The more emphasis put on money, the more people will defile themselves to new levels of overt individualism. In a money-orientated world, people will hold others in disdain for increasingly insignificant reasons. Abound in society are multitudinous problems and illnesses, some irreparable and insurmountable; others rectifiable and surmountable. It is the former that need more attention and funding. The ones stemming from income inequality – crime, obesity, mental health problems, drug and alcohol dependency, debt dependency, lack of equality of opportunity, poverty, and so on – constitute the latter; they are neither irreparable nor insurmountable. They all have a common denominator: income inequality; it is the underlying spurring factor; without the process, the resultant problems would not be in society to the extent they are. If the process is not hampered, and ultimately eradicated, then these problems will only worsen. It is a contagion as such – uninhibited, income inequality will spread and go to more extreme levels, as will these associative problems; inhibited, income inequality will become more palatable and sufferable. Our encounter with income inequality to date has been wholly negative. It has brought nothing but harm and misery. If left uninhibited, and on the basis of our past experience, what hope is there for a more civil, fair, and just society? There will be no hope - and left, for our successors, our posterity, will be a society filled with envy, deceit, and iniquity. To end (it's been a journey, I know), I will leave a quote which, in my eyes, effectively sums up the present income inequality, by the revered economist, Vilfredo Pareto:

If a certain measure A is the cause of a loss of one franc to each of a thousand persons, and of a thousand franc gain to one individual, the latter will expend a great deal of energy, whereas the former will resist weakly; and it is likely that, in the end, the person who is attempting to secure the thousand francs via A will be successful.

Only that, rather than a one-off expropriation of a thousand francs (or whatever currency it may be), what we are seeing before us today, is the same process but placed on an endless repeat cycle.

P.S. Please share this blog with anybody who may have an interest in the area, or better yet someone who is not aware of the great inequalities that seem to go by without notice. Information is everything.